Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11...

24
Leonardo Felli 30 October, 2002 Microeconomics II Lecture 4 Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with an endowment (Labour supply) Define M = m + to be the endowment of the consumer. The Marshallian demand will be: x * = x(p, m + ) Differentiation gives: ∂x l ∂p l m = ∂x l ∂p l M + ∂x l ∂M ω l Standard Slutsky decomposition gives: ∂x l ∂p l M = ∂h l ∂p l - ∂x l ∂M x l . 1

Transcript of Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11...

Page 1: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Leonardo Felli 30 October, 2002

Microeconomics II Lecture 4

Marshallian and Hicksian demands for goods with

an endowment (Labour supply)

Define M = m + p ω to be the endowment of the

consumer.

The Marshallian demand will be:

x∗ = x(p, m + p ω)

Differentiation gives:[∂xl

∂pl

]m

=

[∂xl

∂pl

]M

+∂xl

∂Mωl

Standard Slutsky decomposition gives:[∂xl

∂pl

]M

=∂hl

∂pl− ∂xl

∂Mxl.

1

Page 2: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 2

Substituting one in the other we get:[∂xl

∂pl

]m

=∂hl

∂pl+

∂xl

∂m[ωl − xl].

If as in the labour supply case [ωl − xl] ≥ 0 then we

can get backward bending labour supply (backward

bending leisure demand) with leisure a normal good.

Cross-price effects:

Commodity i and j are net substitutes iff

∂hj

∂pi=

∂hi

∂pj> 0

Commodity i and j are net complements iff

∂hj

∂pi=

∂hi

∂pj< 0

(intuition in terms of own price effect.)

Page 3: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 3

Commodity i is a gross substitute of commodity j

iff∂xi

∂pj> 0

(notice the wording)

Commodity i is a gross complement of commodity

j iff∂xi

∂pj< 0

The Slutsky decomposition can be used to state a

new property of the Marshallian demand.

Page 4: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 4

Indeed, the substitution matrix can be written in

terms of Marshallian demand:

S =

∂x1∂p1

+ x1∂x1∂m · · · ∂x1

∂pL+ xL

∂x1∂m

... . . . ...∂xL∂p1

+ x1∂xL∂m · · · ∂xL

∂pL+ xL

∂xL∂m

such a matrix is symmetric and negative semi-definite.

We now provide the answer to a question known as

the integrability problem.

Question: Given a set of observed (Marshallian

of course) demands x(p, m) under which condi-

tions we are sure that there exists a utility func-

tion of the consumer from which these demands

are derived?

Page 5: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 5

Answer: The answer is positive provided that x(p, m)

satisfy:

1. adding up;

2. homogeneity of degree 0 in (p, m);

3. the Slutsky (substitution) matrix is symmetric

and negative semi-definite.

Page 6: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 6

Revealed Preferences

The integrability conditions are stated in terms of

observed demand functions, however what we actu-

ally observe is rather than the entire demand of a

consumer the choices of the consumer for few values

of the parameters.

Question: Given a finite set of demand data:

(p1, m1), . . . , (pn, mn)

are the consumer choices we observe

x1, . . . , xn

consistent with the standard model of max of util-

ity subject to a budget constraint?

Page 7: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 7

To be able to build the answer we need to define the

revealed preference binary relationship:

1. If the bundle x is chosen and px′ ≤ m then

x revealed preferred to x′

In the case in which the preferences we are trying

to recover satisfy a local non-satiation assumption

then

1’. If the bundle x is chosen and px′ < m then

x strictly revealed preferred to x′

Therefore if for a two points observation of the type:

• for (p, m), x chosen and px′ < m or x strictly

revealed preferred to x′;

• while for (p′, m′), x′ chosen and p′x < m′ or x′

strictly revealed preferred to x

Page 8: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 8

we have to conclude that the data observed are not

consistent with the consumer maximizing his prefer-

ences (satisf. local non-satiation) subject to budget

constraint.

x2

6x1 (p, m)

(p′, m′)

s

s x

x′

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

ee

e

aaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaaa -

Page 9: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 9

In the event, however, that the following relationship

holds: px′ > m and p′x > m′ then the information

available will not allow us to test the utility maxi-

mization theory.

We now have the elements to introduce the Weak

Axiom of Revealed Preferences:

A demand function x(p, m) satisfies the weak ax-

iom of revealed preferences if the following property

holds for any two price-income situations (p, m) and

(p′, m′):

if px(p′, m′) ≤ m and x(p′, m′) 6= x(p, m)

then p′x(p, m) > m′

in other words if x(p, m) is weakly revealed preferred

to x(p′, m′) and they are different consumption bun-

dles then x(p′, m′) cannot be weakly revealed pre-

ferred to x(p, m).

Page 10: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 10

The weak axiom has significant implications on the

effect of price changes on demand.

We need to look at a special kind of price changes.

Imagine a situation in which each change in price

from p to p′ is accompanied by an associated change

in income that makes the consumer’s initial consump-

tion bundle just affordable at the new prices: con-

sumer’s income m′ is then such that

m′ = p′x(p, m)

alternatively income is changed so that:

∆m = ∆px(p, m)

where ∆p = (p′ − p).

This is known as Slutsky income compensation and

Slutsky income compensated price changes.

Page 11: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 11

Result. Suppose that the demand function x(p, m)

satisfies:

• homogeneity of degree zero

• underlying preferences are monotonic (locally

non-satiated)

Then x(p, m) satisfies the weak axiom of revealed

preferences if and only if for any compensated

price change from (p, m) to (p′, p′x(p, m)) we have:

(p′ − p)[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] ≤ 0

with strict inequality whenever x(p, m) 6= x(p′, m′).

Page 12: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 12

Proof: Assume WA holds. Consider the strict in-

equality result. We can rewrite the condition as:

(p′ − p)[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] =

p′[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] − p[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)]

Consider the first term, we know p′x(p, m) = m′ and

by monotonicity we get p′x(p′, m′) = m′ therefore

p′[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] = 0.

Consider the second term. By construction x(p, m)

is affordable under p′, the WA therefore implies:

px(p′, m′) > m

since

px(p, m) = m

we conclude:

p[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] > 0

Page 13: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 13

The opposite implication follows from the observa-

tion that the WA holds if it holds for every compen-

sated price change.

Therefore if the weak axiom does not hold it means

that there exists a compensated price change from

(p′, m′) to (p, m), where px(p′, m′) = m, such that

WA does not hold:

x(p, m) 6= x(p′, m′) and p′x(p, m) ≤ m′.

However, by monotonicity:

p[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] = 0

and

p′[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] ≥ 0

Hence

(p′ − p)[x(p′m′) − x(p, m)] ≥ 0

which is a contradiction.

Page 14: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 14

The inequality we have obtained can be written as:

∆p ∆x ≤ 0

This is known as the compensated law of demand.

When x(p, m) is differentiable the compensated law

of demand becomes:

dp dx ≤ 0

where dm = dpx(p, m).

We then obtain:

dx = Dpx(p, m)dpT + Dmx(p, m)dm

or

dx = Dpx(p, m)dpT + Dmx(p, m)dpx(p, m)

Page 15: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 15

or

dx =[Dpx(p, m) + Dmx(p, m)x(p, m)T

]dpT

which gives us:

dp[Dpx(p, m) + Dmx(p, m)x(p, m)T

]dpT ≤ 0

or

dpS(p, m)dpT ≤ 0

which yields that WA holds iff the substitution ma-

trix is negative semi-definite.

Problem is symmetry.

Page 16: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 16

Question: what is a set of necessary and suffi-

cient conditions that rationalize demand behaviour

as derived from a consumer max utility subject to

budget constraint.

Answer: Strong Axiom of revealed preferences

The demand x(p, m) satisfies the SA iff for any list

(p1, m1), . . . , (pN , mN)

with x(pn+1, mn+1) 6= x(pn, mn) for all n ≤ N − 1

we have:

pNx(p1, m1) > mN

whenever

pnx(pn+1, mn+1) ≤ mn

for any n ≤ N − 1.

Page 17: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 17

In words, if x(p1, m1) is directly or indirectly revealed

preferred to x(pN , mN) then x(pN , mN) cannot be

directly or indirectly revealed preferred to x(p1, m1).

Essentially SA implies that given any finite set of

demand data, it is not possible to construct a cycle

of the type:

xn1 r.p. xn2 r.p. . . . r.p. xn1

where r.p. is strict in at least one case.

Theorem: SA is both a necessary and sufficient

condition for the existence of a utility function

that rationalize the observed behaviour as a util-

ity maximization one.

Page 18: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 18

The hard part of the proof is sufficiency.

The SA is therefore equivalent for an homogeneous of

degree zero Marshallian demand that satisfies adding

up conditions to the symmetry and negative semi-

definiteness of the substitution matrix.

Example of how to use GARP. Consider the following

data:

x1 =

10

10

10

x2 =

9

25

7.5

x3 =

15

5

9

p1 = (10, 10, 10) 300 415 290

p2 = (10, 1, 2) 130 130 173

p3 = (1, 1, 10) 120 109 110

where m1 = 300, m2 = 130 and m3 = 110.

Page 19: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 19

Notice that:

In period t = 1 the price was p1, x1 was chosen but

x3 was affordable:

x1 s.r.p. x3.

In period t = 2 the price was p2, x2 was chosen but

x1 was affordable:

x2 w.r.p. x1.

In period t = 3 the price was p3, x3 was chosen but

x2 was affordable:

x3 s.r.p. x2.

Hence

x2 w.r.p. x1 s.r.p. x3 s.r.p. x2

which violates SA.

Page 20: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 20

Consumer Surplus

Assume that p changes from p0 to p1 (price decrease

p1 ≤ p0 or p1l ≤ p0

l ∀l).

We cannot measure the consumer’s gain in terms of

utility (utility is not cardinal) however we can ask

either of these alternative questions:

1. At the new price level p1 what change in income

would restore the original level of utility for the con-

sumer? This change in income is known as compen-

sating variation CV such that:

V (p0, m) = V (p1, m − CV )

Notice that is p0 ≥ p1 then CV > 0.

Page 21: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 21

2. At the old price level p0 what change in income

would induce the new level of utility for the con-

sumer? This change is known as equivalent varia-

tion EV such that:

V (p1, m) = V (p0, m + EV )

Notice that is p0 ≥ p1 then EV > 0.

Both CV and EV can be defined by means of the

expenditure function (graph):

CV = e(p0, u0) − e(p1, u0) =

=

L∑l=1

∫ p0l

p1l

∂e(p, u0)

∂pldpl

=

L∑l=1

∫ p0l

p1l

hl(p, u0)dpl

by Shephard’s lemma and where u0 is the level of

utility achieved when p = p0.

Page 22: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 22

EV = e(p0, u1) − e(p1, u1) =

=

L∑l=1

∫ p0l

p1l

hl(p, u1)dpl

where u1 is the level of utility when p = p1.

q

6p

-

HHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHHH

HHHHH

p1

p0 ...................................................................

............................................................................................

h(p, u0) h(p, u1)

x(p, m)

.......................................................

...................

q0 q1

Page 23: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 23

These two measures refer to different situations:

CV suitable to compensate individuals once a project

has gone ahead;

EV useful to compare in advance the effect of differ-

ent projects.

As an example assume that only the price of one

commodity pl changes from p0l to p1

l ≤ p0l .

If commodity l is normal the Marshallian demand is

more steep than the Hicksian demand (by Slutsky)

∂xl

∂pl− ∂hl

∂pl= −∂xl

∂mxl < 0

Page 24: Microeconomics II Lecture 4econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/lect412-4.pdfMicroeconomics II 11 Result. Supposethatthedemandfunctionx(p,m) satisfies: • homogeneity of degree zero

Microeconomics II 24

Define the consumer surplus for commodity l when

the price is pl to be:

CS =

∫ p̄l

pl

xl(p, m)dpl

For a normal good:

CV < ∆CS < EV

For an inferior good:

CV > ∆CS > EV

When the income effect is zero:

CV = ∆CS = EV

this is the case for quasi-linear utility function

u(x1, x2) = u(x1) + x2

where∂x1

∂m= 0