EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides...

53
EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 27 October, 2017

Transcript of EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides...

Page 1: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I:Lecture 5

Leonardo Felli

32L.LG.04

27 October, 2017

Page 2: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation

Recall the following result:

Result

An allocation x∗ is Pareto-efficient if and only if there exists avector of weights λ = (λ1, . . . , λI ), λi ≥ 0, for all i ≤ I and λh > 0for at least one h ≤ I , such that x∗ solves the following problem:

maxx1,...,x I

I∑i=1

λi ui (xi )

s.tI∑

i=1

x i ≤ ω(1)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 2 / 53

Page 3: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d)

Recall we proved the only if statement.

Proof: If: If x∗ is Pareto-efficient then there exist λ such that x∗

solves (2).

To prove this implication we need the Second Welfare Theoremand the following Result.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 3 / 53

Page 4: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d)

Result

Let U : RL+ → R be continuously differentiable, concave and

monotonic. Consider the following problem:

maxx∈RN

+

U(x) s.t. p x ≤ p ω

Then there exists a µ > 0 such that

∂U(x)

∂x`= µ p` ∀` = 1, . . . , L

Proof: By Kuhn-Tucker Theorem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 4 / 53

Page 5: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d)

We can now re-state the if statement above as follows.

Result (If:)

Assume that x∗ is a Pareto-efficient allocation with x∗,i > 0 for alli ≤ I , and that ui (·) are monotonic, concave and continuouslydifferentiable.

Then there exists an I -tuple λ1, . . . , λI > 0 such that x∗ solves theplanner’s problem (2).

Moreover, λi is the inverse of the marginal utility of income.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 5 / 53

Page 6: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d)

Proof: By Second Welfare Theorem, since x∗ is Pareto-efficient itis a Walrasian Equilibrium for endowments x∗,i = ωi and a pricevector p∗ > 0.

Therefore for a given p∗ consumers maximize their utility subjectto budget constraint by choosing x∗,i .

In other words, by the result above, there exists a I -tuple:γ1, . . . , γI > 0 such that:

∂ui (x∗,i )

∂x i`= γ i p∗` ∀i , ∀`

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 6 / 53

Page 7: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d)

Consider now the central planner’s Problem:

maxx1,...,x I

I∑i=1

λi ui (xi )

s.tI∑

i=1

x i ≤ ω(2)

It is a concave problem: concave objective function and linearconstraint, therefore x∗ solves it if we can find an L-tupleα1, . . . , αL > 0 such that:

[I∑

i=1

λi ui (x∗,i )

]∂x i`

= α` ∀i , ∀`

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 7 / 53

Page 8: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Pareto Efficient Allocation (cont’d)

or

λi∂ui (x

∗,i )

∂x i`= α` ∀i , ∀`

Choosing now

λi =1

γ iα` = p∗`

and noticing that γ i is the marginal utility of income concludes theproof.

Notice that α` are the shadow prices of the feasibility conditions,and according to the result above correspond to the Walrasianequilibrium prices.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 8 / 53

Page 9: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Production Economy

Consider now an economy with I consumers and J producerscharacterized by their production possibility set Y j .

Define a production economy with private ownership as follows:

E ={

(ω1, . . . , ωI ); ui (·);Y j ; θji , ∀i ≤ I ,∀j ≤ J}

where θji is the share owned by consumer i of firm j , of course:

I∑i=1

θji = 1 ∀j ≤ J

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 9 / 53

Page 10: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Walrasian Equilibrium with Production: Definition

Define a Walrasian equilibrium for a production economy E as:{p∗; (x∗,1, . . . , x∗,I ); (y∗,1, . . . , y∗,J)

}

such that:

x∗,i solves for every i ≤ I :

maxx i

ui (xi ) s.t. p∗x i ≤ p∗ωi +

J∑j=1

θji(p∗y∗,j

)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 10 / 53

Page 11: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Walrasian Equilibrium with Production: Definition (cont’d)

y∗,j solves for every j ≤ J:

maxy j

p∗y j s.t. y j ∈ Y j

and market clearing conditions are satisfied:

I∑i=1

x∗,i −J∑

j=1

y∗,j −I∑

i=1

ωj ≤ 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 11 / 53

Page 12: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Aggregate Excess Demand

Define aggregate excess demand for this economy as:

Z (p) =I∑

i=1

x i (p)−J∑

j=1

y j(p)−I∑

i=1

ωi

where x i (p) is consumer i ’s Marshallian demand and y j(p) is firmj ’s net supply: y j`(p) > 0 is the supply of commodity ` while

y jκ(p) < 0 is minus unconditional factor demand of commodity κ.

Notice that Z (p) is homogeneous of degree zero in p.

Both x i (p) and y j(p) are homogeneous of degree zero in p.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 12 / 53

Page 13: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Walras Law

Walras Law:p Z (p) = 0.

This is obtained once again by summing each consumer’s budgetconstraint:

p x i (p)− p ωi −J∑

j=1

θji(p y j(p)

)= 0

That is:

I∑i=1

p x i (p)−I∑

i=1

p ωi −I∑

i=1

J∑j=1

θji(p y j(p)

)= 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 13 / 53

Page 14: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Walras Law (cont’d)

In other words:

I∑i=1

p x i (p)−I∑

i=1

p ωi −J∑

j=1

(I∑

i=1

θji

) (p y j(p)

)= 0

or

p

I∑i=1

x i (p)−I∑

i=1

ωi −J∑

j=1

y j(p)

= 0

We can now state the three main Theorems we have proved in apure exchange economy for the production economy E .

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 14 / 53

Page 15: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Existence Theorem

Theorem (Existence Theorem)

Consider a Z (p) that satisfies the following conditions:

1. Z (p) is non-empty;

2. Z (p) is convex valued;

3. Z (p) is upper-hemi-continuous;

4. Z (p) is homogeneous of degree 0;

5. Z (p) satisfies Walras Law;

6. Z (p) is bounded;

then there exists p∗ such that

Z (p∗) ≤ 0.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 15 / 53

Page 16: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium

We now move to the properties of Walrasian equilibrium in theproduction economy E .

Definition

An allocation is feasible for a production economy E if and only ifthere exists a production plan y j for every firm j ≤ J such that

y j ∈ Y j ∀j ≤ J

andI∑

i=1

x i ≤I∑

i=1

ωi +J∑

j=1

y j

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 16 / 53

Page 17: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Properties of Walrasian Equilibrium (cont’d)

Definition

An allocation is Pareto-efficient for a production economy E if andonly if

I it is feasible

I and there does not exists an alternative feasible allocation xthat Pareto-dominates it.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 17 / 53

Page 18: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

First Welfare Theorem

Theorem (First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics)

Let E be a production economy with consumer preferencessatisfying weak monotonicity.

Let{p∗; (x∗,1, . . . , x∗,I ); (y∗,1, . . . , y∗,J)

}be a Walrasian

equilibrium for E .

Then x∗ is a Pareto-efficient allocation.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 18 / 53

Page 19: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Second Welfare Theorem

Theorem (Second Welfare Theorem)

Assume that x∗, such that x∗,i > 0, is Pareto-efficient and that

I preferences ui (·) are strongly monotonic;

I preferences are convex: ui (·) are quasi-concave;

I technology Y j is convex for every j ≤ J and 0 ∈ Y j .

Then there exists a redistribution of endowments ωi for i ≤ I anda vector of shares θji , for i ≤ I and j ≤ J such that{

p∗; (x∗,1, . . . , x∗,I ); (y∗,1, . . . , y∗,J)}

is a Walrasian equilibrium for the economy E .

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 19 / 53

Page 20: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Second Welfare Theorem: Lemma

Lemma

Assume that x∗, such that x∗,i > 0, is Pareto-efficient and that:

I preferences are strongly monotonic;

I preferences are convex;

I Y j are convex for every j ≤ J;

I 0 ∈ Y j for every j ≤ J.

Then there exists a y∗,j for every firm j ≤ J and a vector p∗ suchthat:

a)I∑

i=1

x∗,i =J∑

j=1

y∗,j +I∑

i=1

ωi ;

b) ui (x′i ) > ui (x

∗,i ) implies p∗x ′i > p∗x∗,i ;

c) p∗y∗,j ≥ p∗y j for every y j ∈ Y j and every j ≤ J.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 20 / 53

Page 21: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Second Welfare Theorem: Proof

Proof: Given this Lemma we just need to find the re-distributionωi , θji , ∀i , which at p∗ gives exactly

(p∗x∗,i

)to every consumer.

Let V ∗ =I∑

i=1

p∗x∗,i and

V ∗i = p∗x∗,i .

Let also

s i =V ∗iV ∗

be i ’s share of the total value.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 21 / 53

Page 22: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Second Welfare Theorem: Proof (cont’d)

We prove the Theorem by setting:

ωi = s iI∑

i=1

ωi ∀i ≤ I

andθji = s i ∀i ≤ I ∀j ≤ J.

By construction this choice of ωi and θji implies that the budgetconstraint of each agent is satisfied at p∗:

p∗ ωi +J∑

j=1

θji(p∗ y∗,j

)= s i p∗

I∑i=1

ωi +J∑

j=1

y∗,j

=

= s i p∗

(I∑

i=1

x∗,i

)= s i

(I∑

i=1

p∗x∗,i

)= s i V ∗ = V ∗i = p∗ x∗,i

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 22 / 53

Page 23: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities

Definition

An externality is any indirect effect that either a production or aconsumption activity has on a utility function, a consumption setor a production set

An indirect effect is an effect that is:

I created by an economic agent other than the one who isaffected;

I not transmitted through prices.

Example: two firms that pollute each other environment, each oneimposes a negative external effect on the other.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 23 / 53

Page 24: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities (caveat)

Notice that:

I If the two firms merge the pollution effect on each other is notan external effect any more but part of the firm’s technology.

I If a market in pollution rights is created then firm i must buyfrom firm j a pollution right such as it would buy any otherintermediate input: the externalities are incorporated into themarket transactions.

Notice, however, that the general equilibrium model does not treatas endogenous the size of agents and the number of markets. Ittakes them for given.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 24 / 53

Page 25: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Examples

1. A firm polluting a river and thus decreasing the possibilities ofconsuming the water is an externality: the external effect of aproduction activity on a consumption set.

In this case the consumption feasible set is a correspondencethat depends on the production levels of the polluting firm

X i (y j)

In general a production externality is such that:

X i (y1, . . . , yJ)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 25 / 53

Page 26: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Examples (cont’d)

2. The noise emanating from the stereo system of one’s neighboris a typical consumption externality.

The utility function of the concerned consumer i depends onconsumer’s j ’s music consumption x jm:

ui (x i , x jm)

In general, a consumption externality is characterized by:

ui (x1, . . . , x I )

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 26 / 53

Page 27: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Examples (cont’d)

3. Meade (1952)’s famous example of the beekeeper and theorchard is a typical example of a mutual productionexternality.

The production function of each firm depends on the input ofthe other firm:

f 1(x1, x2), f 2(x1, x2)

In general, the PPS of both firms is a correspondence thatdepends on the production plan of all firms:

Y j(y1, . . . , yJ)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 27 / 53

Page 28: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy

Consider a Robinson Crusoe’s economy.

There exists a single consumer, two goods and two firms.

Clearly in this economy there is no issue of who owns the firms.

Assume that there are two externalities imposed on firm 2:

I an externality generated by the consumer’s consumption ofgood 1: x1;

I an externality generated by firm 1’s production of good 1: y11 .

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 28 / 53

Page 29: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

The consumer’s preferences are: u(x1, x2).

Firm 1’s technology: y11 = f 1(y1

2 ) (differentiable and concave).Recall that by sign convention y1

2 is negative.

Firm 2’s technology: y22 = f 2(y2

1 , y11 , x1) (differentiable and

concave). Recall that by sign convention y21 is negative.

Let ω = (ω1, ω2) be the consumer’s endowment vector.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 29 / 53

Page 30: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

We consider first the Pareto efficient allocation.

This is the solution to the following central planner’s problem:

max{x1,x2,y1

1 ,y12 ,y

21 ,y

22 }

U(x1, x2)

s.t. x1 ≤ ω1 + y11 + y2

1

x2 ≤ ω2 + y12 + y2

2

y11 = f 1(y1

2 )

y22 = f 2(y2

1 , y11 , x1)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 30 / 53

Page 31: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

Consider now the necessary and sufficient first order conditions:

∂U

∂x1− λ1 + µ2

∂f 2

∂x1= 0

∂U

∂x2− λ2 = 0

λ1 − µ1 + µ2∂f 2

∂y11

= 0

λ2 + µ1∂f 1

∂y12

= 0

λ2 − µ2 = 0

λ1 + µ2∂f 2

∂y21

= 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 31 / 53

Page 32: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

They can be re-written as:

∂U

∂x1+∂U

∂x2

∂f 2

∂x1

∂U

∂x2

= −∂f2

∂y21

= −1 +

∂f 2

∂y11

d f 1

d y12

d f 1

d y12

This corresponds to the equality of:

I the social marginal rate of substitution, that takes theconsumption externality into account,

I the social marginal rate of transformation of firm 2, thatcoincides with the private one,

I the social marginal rate of transformation of firm 1, that takesthe production externality into account.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 32 / 53

Page 33: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

Consider now the Walrasian equilibrium of this economy.

Notice that the key assumption is that each individual agentconsiders as parameters not only the prices but also the othervariables that characterize his decision set.

In particular, these variables — y11 and x1 for firm 2 — must be

equal to the choices of the other agents.

Let p = (p1, p2) be the vector of prices in this perfectlycompetitive economy.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 33 / 53

Page 34: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

Firm 1’s maximization problem is clearly not affected byexternalities:

max{y1

1 ,y12 }

p1 y11 + p2y

12

s.t. y11 = f 1(y1

2 )

The private marginal rate of transformation equals the price ratio:

− 1

d f 1

d y12

=p1

p2

Let y∗,1 = (y∗,11 , y∗,12 ) be the solution to this problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 34 / 53

Page 35: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

The consumer’s utility maximization problem is also not affectedby externalities:

max{x1,x2}

U(x1, x2)

s.t. p1 x1 + p2x2 ≤ p1 ω1 + p2 ω2 + Π(p1, p2)

where

Π(p1, p2) = (p1 y∗,11 + p2 y

∗,12 ) + (p1 y

∗,21 + p2 y

∗,22 )

The private marginal rate of substitution equals the price ratio:

∂U/∂x1

∂U/∂x2=

p1

p2

Let x∗ = (x∗1 , x∗2 ) be the solution to this problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 35 / 53

Page 36: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

Firm 2 is affected by the externalities, from firm 2’s view point y∗,11

and x∗1 are given, it cannot control them:

max{y2

1 ,y22 }

p1 y21 + p2y

22

s.t. y22 = f 2(y2

1 , y∗,11 , x∗1 )

The private marginal rate of transformation equals the price ratio:

−∂f 2(y2

1 , y∗,11 , x∗1 )

∂y21

=p1

p2

Let y∗,2 = (y∗,21 , y∗,22 ) be the solution to this problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 36 / 53

Page 37: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

Therefore the Walrasian equilibrium of this economy is a vector ofprices

p∗ = (p∗1 , p∗2)

and an allocation{x∗, y∗,1, y∗,2}

such that:

I The allocation {x∗, y∗,1, y∗,2} solves the three problems abovegiven the vector of prices p∗;

I Markets clear:

x∗1 = ω1 + y∗,11 + y∗,21

x∗2 = ω2 + y∗,12 + y∗,22

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 37 / 53

Page 38: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Externalities: Robinson Crusoe’s Economy (cont’d)

The key comparison is the one between the two marginalconditions that define the Pareto efficient allocation:

∂U

∂x1+∂U

∂x2

∂f 2

∂x1

∂U

∂x2

= −∂f2

∂y21

= −1 +

∂f 2

∂y11

d f 1

d y12

d f 1

d y12

and the two marginal conditions that define the Walrasianequilibrium allocation:

∂U

∂x1

∂U

∂x2

= −∂f2

∂y21

= − 1

d f 1

d y12

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 38 / 53

Page 39: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Failure of First Welfare Theorem

Result

The Walrasian equilibrium of an economy with externalities is notPareto efficient.

In other words in the presence of externalities the First WelfareTheorem does not hold.

In general, economic decisions appear to be too decentralized at aWalrasian equilibrium allocation: they do not take into account theexternal effect that individual decisions have on other agents.

In general:

I a firm exercising a negative externality will produce too much,

I a firm exercising a positive externality will produce too little.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 39 / 53

Page 40: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Incomplete Markets

One way to interpret the inefficiency we identified is in terms ofincomplete markets

In other words, in the economy we considered two markets do notexist:

I the market through which firm 1 acquires the right to exert anexternality on firm 2;

I the market through which the consumer acquires the right toexert an externality on firm 2.

One way to amend the inefficiency is to establish firm 2’sownership rights on its production activity and hence create themissing markets.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 40 / 53

Page 41: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Completing Markets

Assume that both these markets are perfectly competitive (verystrong assumption).

Let

I q1,21 be the price at which firm 1 must buy from firm 2 the

right to exercise its externality,

I p1,21 be the price at which the consumer must buy from firm 2

the right to exercise her externality.

Let now (p1, p2, q1,21 , p1,2

1 ) be the vector of prices of this redefinedperfectly competitive economy.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 41 / 53

Page 42: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Completing Markets (cont’d)

Firm 1’s maximization problem is now:

max{y1

1 ,y12 ,y

1,21 }

p1 y11 + p2y

12 − q1,2

1 y1,21

s.t. y11 = f 1(y1

2 )

y1,21 = y1

1

Enforcement of ownership rights implies that y1,21 = y1

1 . Themarginal condition is now:

− 1

d f 1

d y12

=(p1 − q1,2

1 )

p2

Let (y11 , y

12 , y

1,21 ) be the solution to this problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 42 / 53

Page 43: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Completing Markets (cont’d)

The consumer’s utility maximization problem is now:

max{x1,x2,x

1,21 }

U(x1, x2)

s.t. p1 x1 + p2x2 + p1,21 x1,2

1 ≤ p1 ω1 + p2 ω2 + Π

x1,21 = x1

where

Π = (p1 y11 +p2 y

12 −q1,2

1 y1,21 )+(p1 y

21 +p2 y

22 +q1,2

1 y1,21 +p1,2

1 x1,21 )

The marginal condition is then:

∂U/∂x1

∂U/∂x2=

p1 + p1,21

p2

Let (x1, x2, x1,21 ) be the solution to this problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 43 / 53

Page 44: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Completing Markets (cont’d)

Firm 2 controls the supply of the externality rights (y1,21 , x1,2

1 )therefore its maximization problem is now:

max{y2

1 ,y22 ,y

1,21 ,x1,2

1 }p1 y

21 + p2y

22 + q1,2

1 y1,21 + p1,2

1 x1,21

s.t. y22 = f 2(y2

1 , y11 , x1)

The marginal conditions are then:

p2∂f 2

∂y21

+ p1 = p2∂f 2

∂y1,21

+ q1,21 = p2

∂f 2

∂x1,21

+ p1,21 = 0

Let (y21 , y

22 , ˆy

1,21 , ˆx1,2

1 ) be the solution to this problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 44 / 53

Page 45: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Completing Markets (cont’d)

Therefore the Walrasian equilibrium of this economy is a vector ofprices

(p1, p2, q1,21 , p1,2

1 )

and an allocation

{(x1, x2, x1,21 ), (y1

1 , y12 , y

1,21 ), (y2

1 , y22 , ˆy

1,21 , ˆx1,2

1 )}

such that:

I The allocation solves the three problems above given thevector of prices;

I Markets clear:

x∗1 = ω1 + y∗.11 + y∗,21ˆy1,21 = y1,2

1

x∗2 = ω2 + y∗.12 + y∗,22ˆx1,2

1 = x1,21

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 45 / 53

Page 46: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Completing Markets (cont’d)

Putting together the marginal conditions that define the Walrasianequilibrium we now conclude that:

∂U

∂x1+∂U

∂x2

∂f 2

∂x1

∂U

∂x2

= −∂f2

∂y21

= −1 +

∂f 2

∂y11

d f 1

d y12

d f 1

d y12

In other words, when markets are complete the Walrasianequilibrium allocation is Pareto efficient: the First WelfareTheorem holds.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 46 / 53

Page 47: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Observation

Observation (Coase 1960)

Provided markets are complete it does not matter for Paretoefficiency how property rights are allocated.

Assume that firm 1 is allocated ownership rights on a quantity Qof externality and any reduction in this quantity has to bepurchased from firm 1.

Similarly assume that the consumer is allocated ownership rightson an amount x of externality and any reduction has to bepurchased from the consumer.

Let once again (p1, p2, q1,21 , p1,2

1 ) be the vector of prices of thisredefined perfectly competitive economy.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 47 / 53

Page 48: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Observation (cont’d)

The consumer’s utility maximization problem is then:

max{x1,x2,x

1,21 }

U(x1, x2)

s.t. p1 x1 + p2x2 ≤ p1 ω1 + p2 ω2 + Π + p1,21 (x − x1,2

1 )

x1,21 = x1

where Π is the total profit of firm 1 and 2, and (x − x1,21 ) is the

amount of externality that the consumer supplies.

The budget constraint can then be re-written as:

p1 x1 + p2x2 + p1,21 x1,2

1 ≤ p1 ω1 + p2 ω2 + Π + p1,21 x

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 48 / 53

Page 49: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Observation (cont’d)

Therefore the marginal condition is the same as the one above:

∂U/∂x1

∂U/∂x2=

p1 + p1,21

p2

Similarly for firm 1.Putting together the marginal conditions that define the Walrasianequilibrium we obtain once again:

∂U

∂x1+∂U

∂x2

∂f 2

∂x1

∂U

∂x2

= −∂f2

∂y21

= −1 +

∂f 2

∂y11

d f 1

d y12

d f 1

d y12

In other words, the allocation of property right affects thedistribution of surplus but does not affect the Pareto efficiency ofthe allocation (we will come back to the Coase Theorem).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 49 / 53

Page 50: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Public Goods

Definition

A good is public if its use by one agent does not prevent otheragents from using it. Individual consumption does not exhaust thegood.

Examples: national defense, pollution abatement programs etc...

In general this definition is not as clear cut as it seems: voluntarysubscription, size of the group affected, congestion.

However, we will focus on pure public good: non-rivalry andnon-exclusive.

Subscription is not required, everyone is affected collectively, andthere is no possibility of congestion.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 50 / 53

Page 51: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Public Goods (cont’d)

Consider an economy with I consumers and two good: one privatez and one public y .

Good y is produced, using the private good in the quantity z , bymeans of the following DRS technology:

y = g(z), g ′ > 0, g ′′ < 0

Preferences:U i (x i , y)

Let ω be the aggregate endowment of the private good.

We characterize first the Pareto-efficient allocation.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 51 / 53

Page 52: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Public Goods (cont’d)

The central planner’s problem:

max{x i ,∀i ,y ,z}

I∑i=1

λi U i (x i , y)

s.t.I∑

i=1

x i + z ≤ ω

y = g(z)

The first order conditions are:

λi∂U i

∂x i= µ, ∀i ,

I∑i=1

λi∂U i

∂y= ν, ν g ′(z) = µ

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 52 / 53

Page 53: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 5.pdf · EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04

Public Goods (cont’d)

We then obtain the following Bowen-Lindahl-Samuelson marginalcondition:

I∑i=1

∂U i/∂y

∂U i/∂x i=

1

g ′(z)

In other words, the sum of all consumers’ marginal rate ofsubstitution between the public and the private good must equalthe marginal rate of transformation (in the technology) betweenthese two goods.

Key question: are there decentralized resource-allocationmechanisms that yield a Pareto-optimal allocation?

We will come back to the answer to this question

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 27 October, 2017 53 / 53