Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

32
Advanced Microeconomics Advanced Microeconomics ECON5200 - Fall 2014

Transcript of Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Page 1: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Advanced Microeconomics

ECON5200 - Fall 2014

Page 2: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Adverse Selection

Adverse SelectionGeneral Framework

I q ∈ Q and θ ∈ Θ ≡[θ, θ]distributed according to F (·);

I Agent’s preference U (q, t; θ) = V (q, θ)− t;

I Principal’s preference t − C (q, θ);

I P’s problem under full info:

max(t ,q)

t − C (q, θ)

s.t.:V (q, θ)− t ≥ 0

I FB allocation is Cq(qFB (θ) , θ

)= Vq

(qFB (θ) , θ

)and

tFB (θ) = V(qFB (θ) , θ

).

Page 3: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Adverse Selection

Adverse SelectionGeneral Framework: Implementability

I Let r (θ) ≡ V (q (θ) , θ)− t (θ) the agent’s rent;I Then r (θ) ≥ 0 and r (θ) = maxθ̃ V

(q(θ̃), θ)− t

(θ̃);

I Spence-Mirrlees condition (i.e. single-crossing property)Vqθ (q, θ) ≥ 0 for each q, θ;

TheoremIf single-crossing property holds, then (q (·) , r (·)) is incentivecompatible iff qθ (θ) ≥ 0

r (θ) = r (θ) +∫ θ

θVθ (q (s) , s) ds

Proof.(See notes!).

Page 4: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Adverse Selection

Adverse SelectionGeneral Framework: Optimality

P’s problem under incomplete info:

max(t(·),q(·))

∫ θ̄

θ[t (θ)− C (q (θ) , θ)] f (θ) dθ

s.t.:

V (q (θ) , θ)− t (θ) ≥ 0, ∀θ

V (q (θ) , θ)− t (θ) ≥ V(q(θ̃), θ)− t

(θ̃), ∀θ, θ̃

Page 5: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Adverse Selection

Adverse SelectionGeneral Framework: Optimality

By using the Theorem, the P’s problem is:

max(t(·),q(·))

∫ θ̄

θ[V (q (θ) , θ)− C (q (θ) , θ)− r (θ)] f (θ) dθ

s.t.:

r (θ) ≥ 0, ∀θ

r (θ) = r (θ) +∫ θ

θVθ (q (s) , s) ds, ∀θ, θ̃

qθ (θ) > 0

Additional assumption Vθ (q (θ) , θ) ≥ 0. (See notes!).

Page 6: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Markets and Information

I Fundamental welfare theorems rely on perfect observability ofall commodities to all market participants;

I Often in a transaction one party knows something that otherparties don’t know;

I We study three types of equilibria:

i. Adverse selection: An informed individual’s trading decisionsadversely affects uninformed market participants;

ii. Signaling : Informed individuals signal information about theirunobservable knowledge through observable signal;

iii. Screening : Uninformed parties develop mechanisms to screeninformed individuals with different information.

Page 7: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse Selection (Akerlof, 1970)

I Consider a labor market with many identical potential firms;

I Firms want to hire workers to produce final good by adoptinga constant return to scale technology with labor as the soleinput;

I Firms are risk-neutral, price-taker and profit maximizer;

I The price of the firm’s output is equal to one;

I Workers differ in productivity, θ ∈[θ, θ]distributed according

to F (θ);

I r (θ) is the reservation wage of workers, i.e. the gain theymight obtain by working at home.

Page 8: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse SelectionPerfect Observability

I Due to the assumptions of perfect competition and CRS thefirms would set a wage equal to:

w ∗ (θ) = θ

I Only the workers with {θ|r (θ) ≤ θ} would accept the offer;

I The equilibrium is Pareto optimal.

Page 9: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse SelectionImperfect Observability

DefinitionIn a competitive labor market with unobservable productivitylevels, a competitive equilibrium is the pair {w ∗,Θ∗} such that:

Θ∗ = {θ|r (θ) < w ∗}w ∗ = E (θ|θ ∈ Θ∗)

I The equilibrium is characterized by a fixed point;

I Typically this equilibrium will not be Pareto optimal.

Page 10: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse Selection

I Suppose r (θ) = r and F (r) ∈ (0, 1);

I The Pareto optimal allocation is: if θ ≥ r accept employmentand if θ < r not accept;

I If w > r then Θ∗ =[θ, θ], if w < r then Θ∗ = ∅;

I In both cases w = E (θ): Firms are unable to distinguishamong workers’productivity. Thus, the equilibrium outcomeis ineffi cient:

i. If the share of good workers is large enough, then E (θ) > rand too many workers are hired;

ii. If the share of bad workers is large enough, then E (θ) < r andtoo few workers are hired.

Page 11: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse Selection

I Adverse selection occurs when an informed individual’sdecision depends on her unobservable characteristics andadversely affects the uninformed agents;

I In the labor market context, adverse selection arises when onlyrelatively less capable workers accept a firm’s employmentoffer at any given wage;

I If r(θ) is no longer constant adverse selection arises(specifically if it is increasing!).

Page 12: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse SelectionSuppose r(θ) ≤ θ for all θ and r ′(θ):

Page 13: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Adverse SelectionPossibility of multiple equilibria:

Page 14: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

I Both the firms and the high-ability workers have incentives totransmit information;

I Market responses to the problem of adverse selection:

i. Signaling : Informed individuals (workers) choose their level ofeducation to signal information about their ability touninformed parties (the firms);

ii. Screening : Uninformed parties (firms) take steps to screen thevarious types of individuals on the other side of the market(workers).

Page 15: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Signaling (Spence 1973, 1974)

I Two types of workers: high ability, θH , and low ability, θL;

I The probability of high type workers ( exogenous share in thepopulation) is λ ∈ (0, 1);

I Perfect competitive markets (zero profits), whose profit’sfirms is π = θ − w .

Page 16: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingFull Information

I Bertrand competition outcome;

I (wL,wH ) such that wH = θH and wL = θL;

I If abilities are not observable, then w = E (θ|θ ∈ Θ∗) whereΘ∗ is equal to the set of types accepting the contract.

Page 17: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingImperfect Observability

I Suppose that before entering the job market a worker can getsome level of education, e, and the firms observe it;

I Assume that:

i. Education does not increase workers’productivity;

ii. Education is more costly for the low ability worker than for thehigh ability worker, also at the margin (single crossingproperty);

I Workers’payoff u = w − c (e, θ) with c (0, θ) = 0,ce (e, θ) > 0, cθ (e, θ) < 0 and ceθ (e, θ) < 0.

Page 18: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingWelfare

Welfare effect is generally ambiguous:

I Signaling can lead to a more effi cient allocation of workers’labor and to a Pareto improvement;

I Signaling is a costly activity and workers’welfare may bereduced.

Page 19: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingTiming

I Nature determines worker’s type;

I Worker chooses an education level contingent on his type;

I Conditional on the education level, firms make wage offerssimultaneously

I Worker decides which offer to accept, if any.

Page 20: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingPerfect Bayesian Equilibrium

I We use the concept of Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium;

I The worker’s strategy is optimal given the firm’s strategy;

I µ (e) are the up-dated firms’beliefs that the worker ishigh-type;

I Each firm’s wage offer, following the choice e, is optimal giventhe belief µ (e), the worker’s strategy and the other firms’strategy.

Page 21: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingPerfect Bayesian Equilibrium

The firms’(pure strategy) Nash equilibrium wage offers equal theworker’s expected productivity:

w (e) = µ (e) θH + (1− µ (e)) θL

Page 22: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingSeparating Equilibrium

I Let e∗(θ) the educational equilibrium choice of type θ andw ∗(e) the equilibrium wage of a worker who displays aneducational level of e;

I In any separating equilibrium e∗(θH ) 6= e∗(θL) andw ∗ (e∗(θH )) = θH and w ∗ (e∗(θL)) = θL;

I e∗(θL) = 0, which implies that the low ability worker receivesutility equal to θL at the separating equilibrium.

Page 23: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Signaling

Example (15 - Education and Signaling - See notes!)

I θH = 2, θL = 1, c (e, θ) = eθ ;

I Find the separating PBNE.

Page 24: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

SignalingPooling Equilibrium

I The two types of workers choose the same level of educatione∗(θL) = e∗(θH ) = e∗;

I This implies that w ∗ (e∗) = λθH + (1− λ) θL;

I Any education level between 0 and e ′ can be sustained as apooling equilibrium. e ′ corresponds to the level of educationsuch that low type receives zero utility with w = E [θ], e ′:w − c(e ′(θL), θL) = 0.

Page 25: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

Screening

I Workers’outside option is zero r(θi ) = 0;

I Jobs may differ in the “task level” t > 0 required. (Ex.different number of ours per week);

I The output of a type-θi worker is θi regardless of the worker’stask level. Higher task levels only affect workers’utility. Theyare costly for the workers;

I Workers’payoff u = w − c (t, θ) with c (0, θ) = 0,ct (t, θ) > 0, cθ (t, θ) < 0 and ctθ (t, θ) < 0.

Page 26: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningTiming

I Stage 1 : Firms simultaneously announce a menu of contracts(w , t). Each firm may announce any finite numbers ofcontracts;

I Stage 2: Workers decide whether they want to sign a contractand which one to sign:

- If indifferent between signing and not signing a contract, theworker will sign;

- If indifferent between two types of contract, the worker willchoose the contract with the lower task level.

Page 27: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningFull Observability

If abilities are observable equilibrium entails firms offering adifferent contract to each type:

I (w ∗H , t∗H ) = (θH , 0) for high ability workers;

I (w ∗L , t∗L ) = (θL, 0) for low ability workers;

I Workers accept contracts and firms earn zero profits.

Page 28: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningBreak-Even Line

Page 29: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningPooling Equilibria

No pooling equilibria exists:

Page 30: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningSeparating Equilibria

I If (wL, tL) and (wH , tH ) are the contracts signed respectivelyby the low- and the high-ability workers in a separatingequilibrium, then both contracts yield zero profits: wL = θLand wH = θH ;

I This implies that separating equilibria does not allow forcross-subsidies. Separating equilibria are on the break-evenlines;

I In any separating equilibrium, the low-ability workers acceptcontract (wL, tL) = (θL, 0). They receive the same contractas under full information.

Page 31: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningSeparating Equilibria

I In any separating equilibrium the high ability workers acceptcontract (wH , tH ) = (θH , t̃H ) where t̃H is such that:θH − c(t̃H , θL) = θL − c(0, θL) = θL;

I This means that low type is indifferent between contract(θH , t̃H ) and contract (0, θL);

I If tH > t̃H , firms can offer contracts which attract high abilityworkers and make positive profits.

Page 32: Advanced Microeconomics - UiO

Advanced Microeconomics

Markets and Information

ScreeningSeparating Equilibria

I A separating equilibrium exists if the pooled break-even line issuffi ciently far from θH ;

I This means that λ must be suffi ciently low;

I As in the signaling model, asymmetric information leads toPareto ineffi cient outcomes.