Macroeconomics Chapter 71 Consumption, Saving and Investment Chapter 7.

Post on 05-Jan-2016

218 views 1 download

Transcript of Macroeconomics Chapter 71 Consumption, Saving and Investment Chapter 7.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 1

Consumption, Saving and Investment

Chapter 7

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 2

Consumption and Saving

Household budget constraint C + (1/P) · ∆B+ ∆K = π/P + ( w/P )·L + i·( B/P + K) π /P = 0 C+(1/P)·∆B+∆K=(w/P)·L+i·(B/P+K) consumption+ real saving = real income

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 3

Consumption and Saving

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 4

Consumption and Saving

Consumption Over Two Years Year1

C1 + ( B1/ P + K1) − ( B0/ P + K0) =

( w/P)1 · L + i0 · ( B0/ P + K0) consumption in year1 + real saving in year1 =

real income in year1

Year2 C2 + ( B2/ P + K2) − ( B1/ P + K1) =

( w/ P) 2 · L + i1 · ( B1/ P + K1) consumption in year 2 + real saving in year 2 =

real income in year 2

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 5

Consumption and Saving

Consumption Over Two Years Combine the budget constraints to describe a

household’s choice between consuming this year, C1, and next year, C2.

B1/P + K1 =

B0/P + K0 + i0·(B0/P + K0) + ( w/P)1·L− C1

Real assets end year1 =

real assets end year0 + real income year1

− consumption year1

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 6

Consumption and Saving

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 7

Consumption and Saving

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 8

Consumption and Saving

Consumption Over Two Years B1/P + K1 =

(1+i0) · (B0/P + K0) + (w/P)1 · L − C1

B2/P + K2 =

(1+ i1) · (B1/P + K1) + (w/P)2 · L − C2

B2/P + K2 =

(1+i1) · [(1+i0)·( B0/P + K0) + (w/P)1·L − C1]

+ (w/P)2 · L − C2

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 9

Consumption and Saving

Consumption Over Two Years C2+(1+i1)· C1 = (1+i1)·(1+i0)·(B0/P+K0)

+(1+i1)·(w/P)1·L+(w/P)2·L - (B2/P + K2)

Two-year household budget constraint:

C1 + C2/(1+i1) = (1+ i0)·(B0/P+K0) + (w/P)1·L+(w/P)2·L/(1+i1)−(B2/P+K2)/(1+i1)

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 10

Consumption and Saving

Present value If the interest rate, i1, is greater than

zero, $1 received or spent in year 1 is equivalent to more than $1 in year 2.

Dollars received or spent in year 2 must be discounted to make them comparable to dollars in year 1.

The term 1+i1 is called a discount factor.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 11

Consumption and Saving

Household chooses the time path of consumption—in this case, C1 and C2—to maximize utility, subject to the budget constraint.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 12

Consumption and Saving Choosing consumption: income effects

C1 + C2/(1+i1) = (1+ i0)·(B0/P+K0) + (w/P)1·L+(w/P)2·L/(1+i1)−(B2/P+K2)/(1+i1)

p.v. of consumption = value of initial assets + p.v. of wage incomes − p.v. of assets end year 2

V = (1 + i0)·(B0/P+K0) + (w/P)1·L + (w/P)2·L/(1+i1)

p.v. of sources of funds = value of initial assets + p.v. of wage incomes

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 13

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: income effects C1 + C2/(1+i1) = V − (B2/P+K2)/(1+i1) p.v. of consumption = p.v. of sources of funds − p.v. of assets end year 2

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 14

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: income effects Suppose that V increases due to a rise in wage

incomes. Since we are holding fixed the term (B2/P+K2)/(1 + i1), the total present value of consumption, C1 + C2/(1 + i1), must rise by the same amount as V.

Since households like to consume at similar levels in the two years, we predict that C1 and C2 will rise by similar amounts. These responses of consumption to increases in initial assets or wage incomes are called income effects.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 15

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: the intertemporal-substitution effect.

C1 + C2/(1+i1) = V − (B2/P+K2)/(1+i1) p.v. of consumption = p.v. of sources of funds − p.v. of assets end year 2

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 16

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: the intertemporal-substitution effect. A higher i1 provides a greater reward

for deferring consumption. Therefore, the household responds to an increase in i1 by lowering C1 and raising C2.

This response is called the intertemporal-substitution effect.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 17

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: the intertemporal-substitution effect. C1 + (B1/P + K1) − ( B0/P+K0) = (w/P)1·L

+ i0·(B0/P +K0)

Consumption in year1 + real saving in year1 = real income in year 1

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 18

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: the intertemporal-substitution effect. We know from the intertemporal-

substitution effect that an increase in the interest rate, i1, motivates the household to postpone consumption, so that this year’s consumption, C1, falls on the left-hand side.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 19

Consumption and Saving

Choosing consumption: the intertemporal-substitution effect. Since year 1’s real income is given, the decline in C1 must be matched by a rise in year1’s real saving, (B1/P + K1)

− (B0/P + K0).

The intertemporal-substitution effect motivates the household to save more when the interest rate rises.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 20

Consumption and Saving

The income effect from a change in the interest rate C2 + ( B2/ P + K2) − ( B1/ P + K1) =

( w/ P) 2 · L + i1 · ( B1/ P + K1)

The income effect from i1 i1(B1/P)

i1K1

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 21

Consumption and Saving

The income effect from a change in the interest rate i1(B1/P)

For a holder of bonds, the income effect from an increase in i1 is positive.

For an issuer of bonds, the income effect from an increase in i1 is negative.

For the economy as a whole, lending and borrowing must balance

the income effect from the term i1·(B1/P) is zero.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 22

Consumption and Saving

The income effect from a change in the interest rate i1K1

Average household’s holding of claims on capital, K1, is greater than zero.

The term i1K1, the income effect from an increase in i1 is positive.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 23

Consumption and Saving

The income effect from a change in the interest rate In the aggregate, the income effect

from an increase in i1 consists of a zero effect from the term i1·(B1/P) and a positive effect from the term i1K1.

The full income effect from an increase in i1 is positive.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 24

Consumption and Saving

Combining income and substitution effects The effect of an increase in the interest

rate, i1, on year 1’s consumption, C1

The intertemporal substitution effect motivates the household to reduce C1.

An increase in i1 also has a positive income effect, which motivates the household to raise C1.

The overall effect from an increase in i1 on C1 is ambiguous.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 25

Consumption and Saving

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 26

Consumption and Saving

Consumption Over Many Years Two-year budget constraint

C1 + C2/(1+i1) = (1+ i0)·(B0/P+K0)

+ (w/P)1 · L + (w/P)2·L/(1+i1)

− ( B2/P+K2)/(1+i1)

Relax our simplifying assumption that the household could not change the present value of assets held at the end of year 2

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 27

Consumption and Saving

Consumption and income in future years. overall present value of consumption = C1

+ C2/(1 + i1)

+ C3/[(1 + i1)·(1 + i2)] + · · · overall present value of wage incomes = (w/P)1·L

+ (w/ P)2·L/(1+ i1)

+ (w/P)2·L/[(1+i1)·(1+i2)] + · · ·

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 28

Consumption and Saving

Multiyear budget constraint: C1 + C2/(1 + i1) + C3/[(1+i1)·(1+i2)] + · · ·

= (1+ i0)·(B0/P+K0) + (w/P)1·L

+ (w/P)2·L/(1+ i1) + (w/P)2·L/[(1+i1)·(1+i2)] + · · ·

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 29

Consumption and Saving

Multi-Year budget constraint allows the comparison of the effects of temporary and permanent changes in income.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 30

Consumption and Saving Temporary change in income

We predict that the household would respond to a rise in (w/P)1 · L by raising consumption by similar amounts in each year: C1, C2, C3, and so on. This response means, however, that consumption in any particular year, such as year 1, cannot increase very much. Therefore, if (w/P)1 · L rises by one unit, we predict that C1 increases by much less than one unit. To put it another way, the propensity to consume in year 1 out of an extra unit of year 1’s income tends to be small when the extra income is temporary.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 31

Consumption and Saving

temporary change in income If (w/P)1·L rises by one unit on the right-

hand side, C1 rises by much less than one unit on the left-hand side.

Year 1’s real saving, (B1/P + K1) − (B0/P + K0), must rise by nearly one unit on the left-hand side.

The propensity to save in year 1 out of an extra unit of year 1’s income is nearly one when the extra income is temporary.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 32

Consumption and Saving

Permanent increase in wage income (w/P)1·L, (w/P)2·L, (w/P)3·L, and so on each

rise by one unit. It would be possible for the household to

respond by increasing consumption by one unit in each year

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 33

Consumption and Saving Permanent increase in wage income

The prediction is that the propensity to consume out of an extra unit of year 1’s income would be high—close to one—when the extra income is permanent.

The propensity to save in year 1 out of an extra unit of year 1’s income is small when the extra income is permanent.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 34

Consumption and Saving

Consumption Over Many Years Permanent income.

Consumption depends on a long-term average of incomes—which he called permanent income—rather than current income.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 35

Consumption, Saving, and Investment in Equilibrium

Determine the aggregate quantities of consumption and saving.

Determine the aggregate quantity of investment.

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 36

Consumption, Saving, and Investment in Equilibrium

Budget Constraint C + (1/P)·∆B+ ∆K = (w/P)·L + i·(B/P) +

iK i = (R/P − δ )

C+ (1/P)·∆B+ ∆K = (w/P)·L + i·(B/P) + (R/P) · K − δ

K

B = 0 and ∆B = 0

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 37

Consumption, Saving, and Investment in Equilibrium

Budget Constraint C+ ∆K = (w/P)·L + (R/P)·K − δ K

(w/P)·L + (R/P)·K = Y (Real GDP).

C + ∆K = Y −δK Consumption + net investment = real GDP − depreciation = real net domestic product

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 38

Consumption, Saving, and Investment in Equilibrium

The left-hand side of the equation implies that the economy’s net investment, ∆K, is determined by households’ choices of consumption, C.

Given the real net domestic product, one unit more of consumption, C, means one unit less of net investment, ∆K.

This choice of C determines ∆K

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 39

Multiyear budget constraint: C1 + C2/(1 + i1) + C3/[(1+i1)·(1+i2)] + · · · = (1+ i0)·(B0/P+K0) + (w/P)1·L

+ (w/P)2·L/(1+ i1) + (w/P)2·L/[(1+i1)·(1+i2)] + · · ·

Extra: Consumption and Saving

T

tt

s

t

s

T

tt

s

t

s

Yi

ACi 1

1

1

01

1

11

1

1

1

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 40

Extra: Consumption and Saving

1. A simple case with zero interest rate:

0",0',)(1

uuCuUT

tt

Budget constraint:

T

tt

T

tt YAC

10

1

Lagrangian:

T

tt

T

tt

T

tt CYACuL

110

1

)(

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 41

FOC:

Extra: Consumption and Saving

)(' tCu tYAT

CT

t

10

1

• Implication: 1) Permanent income hypothesis The time pattern of income is not important to consumption, but to saving! 2) Saving is future consumption

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 42

Extra: Consumption and Saving

2. The constant interest rate and saving

0",0',)(

1

1

1

uuCuUT

ttt

Budget constraint:

T

ttt

T

ttt Y

rAC

r 10

1 1

1

1

1

T

ttt

T

ttt

T

ttt C

rY

rACuL

110

1 1

1

1

1)(

1

1

Macroeconomics Chapter 7 43

Extra: Consumption and Saving

ttt rCu

1

1)('

1

1

t

rCu

Cu

t

t

1

1

'

' 1

tRtt

tt

Cu

uRCuCu

CCu

'

'''''

1)(

1

1

1

1

1

1

r

C

C

t

t

Example: