Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in...

34
1 Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in Macroeconomics Jim Stock and Mark Watson IAAE 2017 Sapporo June 26, 2017

Transcript of Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in...

Page 1: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

1

Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in Macroeconomics

Jim Stock and Mark Watson

IAAE 2017 Sapporo

June 26, 2017

Page 2: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

2

Causal effects and IV regression

Avg. Causal Effect: E(Y | X = 1) – E(Y | X = 0)

Linear Regression: Y = γ + β X + u E(u | X) = 0 With Controls: Y = β X + γ’W + u X⊥ = X – Proj(X|W) E(u⊥X⊥) = 0 With Instruments, Z:

Relevance: E(X⊥Z⊥) ≠ 0 Exogeneity: E(u⊥Z⊥ ) = 0

Page 3: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

3

Dynamic causal effects and IRFs

Yt = Θ0 εt + Θ1 εt −1 + … = Θ(L)εt nY nε εj,t are "structural shocks": i.i.d. (over j and t) with mean zero. Dynamic ACE:

E(Yi,t+h | εj,t = 1) − E(Yi,t+h | εj,t = 0) = Θh,ij

( = ∂Yi,t+h / ∂ε j ,t )

Page 4: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

4

Estimating dynamic causal effects in macroeconomics Standard Approach:

• Estimate VAR for Y • Assume "invertibility" to relate εt to VAR forecast

errors. • Impose some restrictions on Θ(L) for identification

Alternative Approach:

• Find an "external" instrument Z that captures exogenous variation in one of the structural shocks.

• Use instrument (with or without VAR step) to estimate dynamic causal effects.

Page 5: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

5

Some references on external instruments

VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson (2012), Mertens and Ravn (2013, 2014), Gertler and Karadi (2015), Caldera and Kamps (2017), Montiel Olea, Stock and Watson (2012), Lumsford (2015), Jentsch and Lunsford (2016), Carriero, Momtaz, Theodoridis and Theophilopoulou (2015), … Local-projections: Jordà, Schularick, and Taylor (2015), Ramey and Zubairy (2017), Ramey (2016), Mertens (2015), Fieldhouse, Mertens, Ravn (2017) …

This talk: Survey-ish

Page 6: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

6

A Running Empirical Example: Gertler-Karadi (2015)

• Yt = (Rt, 100×Δln(IP), 100×Δln(CPI), EBP)

• Monetary policy shock = ε1,t

• Causal Effects: E(Yi,t+h | ε1,t = 1) − E(Yi,t+h | ε1,t = 0) = Θh,i

• Kuttner (2001)-like instrument, Zt = change in Federal

Funds rate futures in short window around FOMC announcements.

o Zt correlated with ε1,t but uncorrelated with

ε•,t = (ε2,t ,ε3,t ,…,εnε ,t ).

Page 7: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

7

ε1,t isDirect estimation of Θh,i1

Yt = Θ0 εt + Θ1 εt −1 + … = Θ(L)εt

Yi,t+h = Θh,i1 ε1,t + ut (LP)

ut = {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

E(ε1,tut) = 0

But ε1,t is not observed

Page 8: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

8

Unit-Effect Normalization – 1

GK – IRF or Monetary Policy Shock

VOL.7 NO.1 61GERTLER AND KARADI: MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES

We begin with the external instruments case. As noted earlier, we use the three month ahead funds rate future surprise FF4 to identify monetary policy shock. As a check to ensure that this instrument is valid, we report the F-statistic from the first stage regression of the one-year bond rate residual on FF4. We find an F-value of 21 and half. We also compute a robust F-statistic (which allows for heteroskedasticity) of 17.5. Both values are safely above the threshold suggested by Stock et al. (2002) to rule out a reasonable likelihood of a weak instruments problem.

As the top left panel shows, a one standard deviation surprise monetary tight-ening induces a roughly 25 basis point increase in the one-year government bond rate. Consistent with conventional theory, there is a significant decline in industrial production that reaches a trough roughly a year and a half after the shock. Similarly consistent with standard theory, there is a small decline in the consumer price index that is not statistically significant. Note that in contrast to the Cholesky identifica-tion, we do not impose zero restrictions on the contemporaneous responses of output and inflation. The identification of the monetary policy shock is entirely due to the external instrument.

regression is incorporated in the reported confidence bands, because both stages of the estimation are included in the bootstrapping procedure. Thereby, we avoid any potential “generated regressor” problem.

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year ratePe

rcen

t

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perc

ent

First-stage regression: F: 21.55; Robust F: 17.64; R

2: 7.76 percent; Adjusted R 2: 7.40 percent

External instruments Cholesky

Figure 1. One-Year Rate Shock with Excess Bond Premium

VOL.7 NO.1 61GERTLER AND KARADI: MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES

We begin with the external instruments case. As noted earlier, we use the three month ahead funds rate future surprise FF4 to identify monetary policy shock. As a check to ensure that this instrument is valid, we report the F-statistic from the first stage regression of the one-year bond rate residual on FF4. We find an F-value of 21 and half. We also compute a robust F-statistic (which allows for heteroskedasticity) of 17.5. Both values are safely above the threshold suggested by Stock et al. (2002) to rule out a reasonable likelihood of a weak instruments problem.

As the top left panel shows, a one standard deviation surprise monetary tight-ening induces a roughly 25 basis point increase in the one-year government bond rate. Consistent with conventional theory, there is a significant decline in industrial production that reaches a trough roughly a year and a half after the shock. Similarly consistent with standard theory, there is a small decline in the consumer price index that is not statistically significant. Note that in contrast to the Cholesky identifica-tion, we do not impose zero restrictions on the contemporaneous responses of output and inflation. The identification of the monetary policy shock is entirely due to the external instrument.

regression is incorporated in the reported confidence bands, because both stages of the estimation are included in the bootstrapping procedure. Thereby, we avoid any potential “generated regressor” problem.

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perc

ent

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perc

ent

First-stage regression: F: 21.55; Robust F: 17.64; R

2: 7.76 percent; Adjusted R 2: 7.40 percent

External instruments Cholesky

Figure 1. One-Year Rate Shock with Excess Bond Premium

Page 9: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

9

Unit-Effect Normalization - 1

Parameters of interest: ∂ IPt+h / ∂ε1,t

∂Rt / ∂ε1,t

VOL.7 NO.1 61GERTLER AND KARADI: MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES

We begin with the external instruments case. As noted earlier, we use the three month ahead funds rate future surprise FF4 to identify monetary policy shock. As a check to ensure that this instrument is valid, we report the F-statistic from the first stage regression of the one-year bond rate residual on FF4. We find an F-value of 21 and half. We also compute a robust F-statistic (which allows for heteroskedasticity) of 17.5. Both values are safely above the threshold suggested by Stock et al. (2002) to rule out a reasonable likelihood of a weak instruments problem.

As the top left panel shows, a one standard deviation surprise monetary tight-ening induces a roughly 25 basis point increase in the one-year government bond rate. Consistent with conventional theory, there is a significant decline in industrial production that reaches a trough roughly a year and a half after the shock. Similarly consistent with standard theory, there is a small decline in the consumer price index that is not statistically significant. Note that in contrast to the Cholesky identifica-tion, we do not impose zero restrictions on the contemporaneous responses of output and inflation. The identification of the monetary policy shock is entirely due to the external instrument.

regression is incorporated in the reported confidence bands, because both stages of the estimation are included in the bootstrapping procedure. Thereby, we avoid any potential “generated regressor” problem.

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perce

nt

First-stage regression: F: 21.55; Robust F: 17.64; R

2: 7.76 percent; Adjusted R 2: 7.40 percent

External instruments Cholesky

Figure 1. One-Year Rate Shock with Excess Bond Premium

VOL.7 NO.1 61GERTLER AND KARADI: MONETARY POLICY SURPRISES

We begin with the external instruments case. As noted earlier, we use the three month ahead funds rate future surprise FF4 to identify monetary policy shock. As a check to ensure that this instrument is valid, we report the F-statistic from the first stage regression of the one-year bond rate residual on FF4. We find an F-value of 21 and half. We also compute a robust F-statistic (which allows for heteroskedasticity) of 17.5. Both values are safely above the threshold suggested by Stock et al. (2002) to rule out a reasonable likelihood of a weak instruments problem.

As the top left panel shows, a one standard deviation surprise monetary tight-ening induces a roughly 25 basis point increase in the one-year government bond rate. Consistent with conventional theory, there is a significant decline in industrial production that reaches a trough roughly a year and a half after the shock. Similarly consistent with standard theory, there is a small decline in the consumer price index that is not statistically significant. Note that in contrast to the Cholesky identifica-tion, we do not impose zero restrictions on the contemporaneous responses of output and inflation. The identification of the monetary policy shock is entirely due to the external instrument.

regression is incorporated in the reported confidence bands, because both stages of the estimation are included in the bootstrapping procedure. Thereby, we avoid any potential “generated regressor” problem.

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perce

nt10 20 30 40

−0.2

0

0.2CPI

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.6−0.4−0.2

00.2

IP

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

One-year rate

Perce

nt

10 20 30 40−0.1

0

0.1

0.2Excess bond premium

Perce

nt

First-stage regression: F: 21.55; Robust F: 17.64; R

2: 7.76 percent; Adjusted R 2: 7.40 percent

External instruments Cholesky

Figure 1. One-Year Rate Shock with Excess Bond Premium

Page 10: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

10

Unit-effect normalization − 2

Θ0,11 = 1

GK: Y1,t = Rt and units are such that ∂Rt / ∂ε1,t = 1

Page 11: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

11

IV estimation of Θh,i2

Yi,t+h = Θh,i1ε1,t + {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

Y1,t = Θ0,11ε1,t + { ε•,t , εt −1, … } = ε1,t + { ε•,t , εt −1, … }

Yi,t+h = Θh,i1Y1,t + {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

Condition LP-IV: (i) E(ε1,t Zt) = α ≠ 0 (ii) E( ε•,t Zt') = 0 (iii) E(εt+j Zt') = 0 for j ≠ 0

Page 12: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

12

Odds and ends • HAR SEs

• Dyn. Causal Effects for levels vs. differences

• Weak-instrument robust inference

• "News" Shocks o replace Θ0,11 = 1 normalization with Θk,11 = 1

normalization

• Smoothness constraints (B&B − today, Plagborg-Møller,)

Page 13: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

13

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)] (1990m1 -2012:m6)

lag (h) (a) R 0 1.00 (0.00) 6 -0.07 (1.34) 12 -1.05 (2.51) 24 -2.09 (5.66) IP 0 -0.59 (0.71) 6 -2.15 (3.42) 12 -3.60 (6.23) 24 -2.99 (10.21) Controls none First-stage F 1.7

Page 14: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

14

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)] (1990m1 -2012:m6)

lag (h) (a) R 0 1.00 (0.00) 6 -0.07 (1.34) 12 -1.05 (2.51) 24 -2.09 (5.66) IP 0 -0.59 (0.71) 6 -2.15 (3.42) 12 -3.60 (6.23) 24 -2.99 (10.21) Controls none First-stage F 1.7

Page 15: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

15

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)] (1990m1 -2012:m6)

lag (h) (a) R 0 1.00 (0.00) 6 -0.07 (1.34) 12 -1.05 (2.51) 24 -2.09 (5.66) IP 0 -0.59 (0.71) 6 -2.15 (3.42) 12 -3.60 (6.23) 24 -2.99 (10.21) Controls none First-stage F 1.7

Page 16: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

16

IV Estimation of Θh,i2 with additional controls -1

Yi,t+h = Θh,i1Y1,t + {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

2 Motivations:

(1) add controls to eliminate part of error term • controls should be uncorrelated with ε1,t. o Examples: lags of Z, Y, other macro variables

(2) Zt may be correlated with error, but uncorrelated after adding controls

(a) Example: GK Z = {ΔFFFt, ΔFFFt −1}. Add lags of FFFt.

Page 17: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

17

IV Estimation of Θh,i2 with additional controls - 2

Yi,t+h = Θh,i1Y1,t + γ'Wt + ut

xt⊥ = xt − Proj(xt | Wt)

Condition LP-IV⊥

(i) E ε1,t

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = ′α ≠ 0

(ii) E ε•,t

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = 0

(iii) E ε t+ j

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = 0 for j ≠ 0.

Page 18: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

18

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)] Yi,t+h = Θh,i1Y1,t + γ'Wt + {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

lag (h) (a) (b) (c) R 0 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 6 -0.07 (1.34) 1.12 (0.52) 0.67 (0.57) 12 -1.05 (2.51) 0.78 (1.02) -0.12 (1.07) 24 -2.09 (5.66) -0.80 (1.53) -1.57 (1.48) IP 0 -0.59 (0.71) 0.21 (0.40) 0.03 (0.55) 6 -2.15 (3.42) -3.80 (3.14) -4.05 (3.65) 12 -3.60 (6.23) -6.70 (4.70) -6.86 (5.49) 24 -2.99 (10.21) -9.51 (7.70) -8.13 (7.62) Controls none 4 lags of (z,y)

4 lags of (z,y,f)

First-stage F 1.7 23.7 18.6

Page 19: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

19

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)] Yi,t+h = Θh,i1Y1,t + γ'Wt + {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

lag (h) (a) (b) (c) R 0 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 6 -0.07 (1.34) 1.12 (0.52) 0.67 (0.57) 12 -1.05 (2.51) 0.78 (1.02) -0.12 (1.07) 24 -2.09 (5.66) -0.80 (1.53) -1.57 (1.48) IP 0 -0.59 (0.71) 0.21 (0.40) 0.03 (0.55) 6 -2.15 (3.42) -3.80 (3.14) -4.05 (3.65) 12 -3.60 (6.23) -6.70 (4.70) -6.86 (5.49) 24 -2.99 (10.21) -9.51 (7.70) -8.13 (7.62) Controls none 4 lags of (z,y)

4 lags of (z,y,f)

First-stage F 1.7 23.7 18.6

Page 20: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

20

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)] Yi,t+h = Θh,i1Y1,t + γ'Wt + {εt+h, … , εt+1, ε•,t , εt −1, … }

lag (h) (a) (b) (c) R 0 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 6 -0.07 (1.34) 1.12 (0.52) 0.67 (0.57) 12 -1.05 (2.51) 0.78 (1.02) -0.12 (1.07) 24 -2.09 (5.66) -0.80 (1.53) -1.57 (1.48) IP 0 -0.59 (0.71) 0.21 (0.40) 0.03 (0.55) 6 -2.15 (3.42) -3.80 (3.14) -4.05 (3.65) 12 -3.60 (6.23) -6.70 (4.70) -6.86 (5.49) 24 -2.99 (10.21) -9.51 (7.70) -8.13 (7.62) Controls none 4 lags of (z,y)

4 lags of (z,y,f)

First-stage F 1.7 23.7 18.6

Page 21: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

21

SVARs with External Instruments - 1

VAR: Yt = A1Yt-1 + A2Yt-2 + … + vt

Structural MA: Yt = Θ0 εt + Θ1 εt −1 + … = Θ(L)εt

Invertibility: εt = Proj(εt|Yt, Yt-1, … ) ⇒

vt = Θ0εt with Θ0 nonsingular (so ny = nε)

Page 22: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

22

SVARs with External Instruments - 2

A(L)Yt = vt = Θ0εt

⇒ Yt = C(L)Θ0εt with C(L)=A(L)-1

thus Θh,i1 = ChΘ0,i1

Unit-effect normalization yields: vi,t = Θ0,i1v1,t + { ε•,t }

Condition SVAR-IV (i) E(ε1,tZt) = α ≠ 0 (ii) E( ε•,t Zt') = 0

Page 23: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

23

SVAR with external instruments – estimation

1. Regress Yi,t onto Y1,t using instruments Zt and p lags of Yt as controls. This yields Θ0,i1

SVAR− IV . 2. Estimate a VAR(p) and invert the VAR to obtain C(L) = A(L)−1 . 3. Estimate the dynamic causal effects of shock 1 on the vector of variables as

Θh,1SVAR− IV = ChΘ0,1

SVAR− IV

(odds and ends: (1) News shocks; (2) Dif. sample periods in (1) and (2))

Page 24: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

24

SVAR with external instruments – inference

• Strong instruments:

T

A− AΘ0,1

SVAR− IV −Θ0,1

⎝⎜⎜

⎠⎟⎟

d⎯ →⎯ Normal + δ-method

• Weak instruments: o T ( A− A) d⎯ →⎯ Normal. o Θ0,1

SVAR− IV −Θ0,1d⎯ →⎯ NonNormal.

o Use weak-instrument robust methods. (Montiel Olea, Stock and Watson (20xx)).

Page 25: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

25

SVAR with external instruments – invertibility 1

VAR forecast error: vt = Yt − Proj(Yt | Yt-1 ) Structural MA: Yt = Θ(L)εt

vt = Θ0εt +

Θh ε t−h − Proj(ε t−h |Y t−1)( )h=1∑

= Θ0εt + "omitted variables" Invertibility: εt = Proj(εt | Yt −1 ), so omitted variables vanish.

Page 26: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

26

SVAR with external instruments – invertibility 2 εt = Proj(εt | Yt −1 ) ⇒

• Proj(Yt| Yt-1, ε t−1) = Proj(Yt| Yt-1 )

• Proj(Yt| Yt-1, X t−1) = Proj(Yt| Yt-1 )

"Getting to invertibility"

• Many Ys • But depends on timing dynamic causal effects (Θ(L)) • No guarantees

Page 27: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

27

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)]

lag (h) LP-IV 1990m1-2012m6

SVAR-IV IV: 1990m1-2012m6

VAR:1980m7-2012m6 R 0 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 6 1.12 (0.52) 0.89 (0.31) 12 0.78 (1.02) 0.78 (0.46) 24 -0.80 (1.53) 0.40 (0.49) IP 0 0.21 (0.40) 0.16 (0.59) 6 -3.80 (3.14) -0.81 (1.19) 12 -6.70 (4.70) -1.87 (1.54) 24 -9.51 (7.70) -2.16 (1.65) Controls 4 lags of (Z,Y)

12 lags of Y 4 lags of Z

First-stage F 23.7 20.5

Page 28: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

28

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)]

lag (h) LP-IV 1990m1-2012m6

SVAR-IV IV: 1990m1-2012m6

VAR:1980m7-2012m6 R 0 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 6 1.12 (0.52) 0.89 (0.31) 12 0.78 (1.02) 0.78 (0.46) 24 -0.80 (1.53) 0.40 (0.49) IP 0 0.21 (0.40) 0.16 (0.59) 6 -3.80 (3.14) -0.81 (1.19) 12 -6.70 (4.70) -1.87 (1.54) 24 -9.51 (7.70) -2.16 (1.65) Controls 4 lags of (Z,Y)

12 lags of Y 4 lags of Z

First-stage F 23.7 20.5

Page 29: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

29

Comparing LP-IV and SVAR-IV - 1 Condition LP-IV⊥

(i) E ε1,t

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = ′α ≠ 0; (ii)

E ε•,t

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = 0

(iii) E ε t+ j

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = 0 for j ≠ 0.

Condition SVAR-IV

(i) E ε1tZt

′( ) = ′α ≠ 0; (ii) E ε•tZt

′( ) = 0

(iii) Invertibility

Page 30: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

30

Comparing LP-IV and SVAR-IV – 2

Suppose (i) E ε1tZt

′( ) = ′α ≠ 0, (ii) E ε•tZt

′( ) = 0, and

E ε1,t+ jZt

′( ) = 0 for j > 0.

Then Wt = (Yt −1) are valid controls for LP-IV (ensuring

E ε t+ j

⊥ Zt⊥′( ) = 0) if and only if the SMA is invertible.

"No Free Lunch"

Page 31: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

31

Comparing LP-IV and SVAR-IV – 3

With strong instruments: Regardless of invertibility, Θh,i1

LP− IV is consistent and asy. normal.

With invertibility, Θh,i1

SVAR− IV is more efficient than Θh,i1LP− IV ,

but Θh,i1SVAR− IV is inconsistent without invertibility ("omitted

variable bias"). Hausman-like test based on Θh,i1

SVAR− IV − Θh,i1LP− IV .

Page 32: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

32

Under strong instruments and "local-to-invertibility"

T θ LP−IV − θSVAR−IV( ) d⎯→⎯ N (d ,V )

ξ= T (θ LP−IV − θSVAR−IV )'V −1(θ LP−IV − θSVAR−IV )

• d is the local departure from invertibility • V = (α2)Ω so instrument strength matters • ξ is a Granger-Causality test (Z → Y), with power

focused on omitted variable bias in SVAR IRFs.

Page 33: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

33

Results for [R and 100 ×ln(IP)]

lag (h) LP-IV SVAR-IV Difference R 0 1.00 (0.00) 1.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 6 1.12 (0.52) 0.89 (0.31) -0.23 (1.19) 12 0.78 (1.02) 0.78 (0.46) 0.00 (1.79) 24 -0.80 (1.53) 0.40 (0.49) 1.19 (2.57) IP 0 0.21 (0.40) 0.16 (0.59) -0.06 (0.35) 6 -3.80 (3.14) -0.81 (1.19) 3.00 (2.32) 12 -6.70 (4.70) -1.87 (1.54) 4.83 (4.00) 24 -9.51 (7.70) -2.16 (1.65) 7.35 (6.40) Controls 4 lags of (Z,Y)

12 lags of Y 4 lags of Z

First-stage F 23.7 20.5

(Overall tests ξ are also statistically insignificant)

Page 34: Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Causal Effects in ...mwatson/slides/Stock-Watson_IAAE_2017...5 Some references on external instruments VARs: Stock (2008), Stock and Watson

34

Left to do

Theory: a little Applications: a lot