EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides...

49
EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 Leonardo Felli 32L.LG.04 6 October, 2017

Transcript of EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides...

Page 1: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I:Lecture 2

Leonardo Felli

32L.LG.04

6 October, 2017

Page 2: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Profit Function

Recall the following property of the profit function

π(p,w) = maxx

p f (x)− w x = p f (x(p,w))− w x(p,w)

I Hotelling’s Lemma:

∂π

∂p= y(p,w) ≥ 0 and

∂π

∂wi= −xi (p,w) ≤ 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 2 / 49

Page 3: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Hessian of the Profit Function

Consider now the Hessian matrix of the profit function π(p,w):

H =

∂2π∂p2

∂2π∂p∂w1

· · · ∂2π∂p∂wh

∂2π∂w1∂p

∂2π∂w2

1· · · ∂2π

∂w1∂wh

......

. . ....

∂2π∂wh∂p

∂2π∂wh∂w1

· · · ∂2π∂w2

h

By Hotelling’s Lemma the matrix H is:

H =

∂y∂p

∂y∂w1

· · · ∂y∂wh

−∂x1∂p − ∂x1

∂w1· · · − ∂x1

∂wh...

.... . .

...

−∂xh∂p − ∂xh

∂w1· · · − ∂xh

∂wh

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 3 / 49

Page 4: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Hessian of the Profit Function

Result

Let F : A→ R where A ⊂ Rn is a convex open set. Let F (·) betwice differentiable. Then the function F (·) is convex if and only ifthe Hessian matrix of F (·) is positive semi-definite on A.

I Recall that the profit function π(p,w) is convex in (p,w).

I This together with Young theorem implies that H issymmetric and has a non negative main diagonal.

I Assume now that π(p,w) is defined on an open and convexset S of prices (p,w) then convexity of π(p,w) is equivalentto the Hessian Matrix H being positive semi-definite.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 4 / 49

Page 5: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Profit Maximization

Profit maximization can be achieved in two sequential steps:

1. Given y , find the choice of inputs that allows the producer toobtain y at the minimum cost;

this generates conditional factor demands and the costfunction;

2. Given the cost function, find the profit maximizing outputlevel.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 5 / 49

Page 6: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Comments

I Notice: step 1 is common to firms that behave competitivelyin the input market but not necessarily in the output market.

I Only in step 2 we impose the competitive assumption on theoutput market.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 6 / 49

Page 7: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Cost Minimization

We shall start from step 1:

minx

w x

s.t. f (x) ≥ y

The necessary first order conditions are:

y = f (x∗),

w ≥ λ∇f (x∗)

and[w − λ∇f (x∗)] x∗ = 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 7 / 49

Page 8: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Cost Minimization (cont’d)

or for every input ` = 1, . . . , h:

w` ≥ λ∂f (x∗)

∂x`

with equality if x∗` > 0.

The first order conditions are also sufficient if f (x) isquasi-concave (the input requirement set is convex).

Alternatively, a set of sufficient conditions for a local minimum arethat f (x) is quasi-concave in a neighborhood of x∗.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 8 / 49

Page 9: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Cost Minimization (cont’d)

This can be checked (sufficient condition) by means of thebordered hessian matrix and its minors.

In the case of only two inputs f (x1, x2) we have:

w` ≥ λ∂f (x∗)

∂x`, ∀` = 1, 2

with equality if x∗` > 0

and SOC: ∣∣∣∣∣∣0 f1(x∗) f2(x∗)

f1(x∗) f11(x∗) f12(x∗)f2(x∗) f21(x∗) f22(x∗)

∣∣∣∣∣∣ > 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 9 / 49

Page 10: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Cost Minimization (cont’d)

In the case the two first order conditions are satisfied with equality(no corner solutions) we can rewrite the necessary conditions as:

MRTS =

∣∣∣∣dx2dx1

∣∣∣∣ =∂f (x∗)/∂x1∂f (x∗)/∂x2

=w1

w2

andy = f (x∗)

Notice a close formal analogy with consumption theory(expenditure minimization).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 10 / 49

Page 11: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Conditional Factor Demands and Cost Function

This leads to define:

I the solution to the cost minimization problem:

x∗ = z(w , y) =

z1(w , y)...

zh(w , y)

the conditional (to y) factor demands (correspondences).

I the minimand function of the cost minimization problem:

c(w , y) = w z(w , y)

the cost function.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 11 / 49

Page 12: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Cost Function

1. c(w , y) is non-decreasing in y .

Proof: Suppose not. Then there exist y ′ < y ′′ such that(denote x ′ and x ′′ the corresponding solution to the costminimization problem)

w x ′ ≥ w x ′′ > 0

If the latter inequality is strict we have an immediatecontradiction of x ′ solving the cost minimization problem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 12 / 49

Page 13: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Cost Function (cont’d)

If on the other hand

w x ′ = w x ′′ > 0

then by continuity and monotonicity of f (·) there existsα ∈ (0, 1) close enough to 1 such that

f (α x ′′) > y ′

andw x ′ > w αx ′′

which contradicts x ′ solving the cost minimizationproblem.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 13 / 49

Page 14: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Cost Function (cont’d)

2. c(w , y) is non-decreasing with respect to w` for every` = 1, . . . , h.

Proof: Consider w ′ and w ′′ such that w ′′` ≥ w ′` but w ′′k = w ′kfor every k 6= `.

Let x ′′ and x ′ be the solutions to the cost minimizationproblem with w ′′ and w ′ respectively.

Then by definition of c(w , y)

c(w ′′, y) = w ′′ x ′′ ≥ w ′ x ′′ ≥ w ′ x ′ = c(w ′, y).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 14 / 49

Page 15: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Cost Function (cont’d)

3. c(w , y) is homogeneous of degree 1 in w .

Proof: The feasible set of the cost minimization problem

f (x) ≥ y

does not change when w is multiplied by the factor t > 0.

Hence ∀t > 0, minimizing (t w) x on this set leads to thesame answer as minimizing w x .

Let x∗ be the solution, then:

c(t w , y) = (t w) x∗ = t c(w , y).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 15 / 49

Page 16: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Cost Function (cont’d)

4. c(w , y) is a concave function in w .

Proof: Let w = t w + (1− t) w ′ for t ∈ [0, 1].

Let x be the solution to the cost minimization problem for w .Then

c(w , y) = w x = t w x + (1− t) w ′ x

≥ t c(w , y) + (1− t) c(w ′, y)

by definition of c(w , y) and c(w ′, y) and f (x) ≥ y .

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 16 / 49

Page 17: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands

5. Shephard’s Lemma:

If z(w , y) is single valued with respect to w then c(w , y) isdifferentiable with respect to w and

∂c(w , y)

∂w`= z`(w , y)

Proof: By constrained Envelope Theorem and the definitionof cost function

c(w , y) = w z(w , y) = w z(w , y)− λ(w , y) [f (z(w , y)− y ]

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 17 / 49

Page 18: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands (cont’d)

6. z(w , y) is homogeneous of degree 0 in w .

Proof: By Shepard’s Lemma and the following result.

Result

If a function G (x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then (∂G/∂x`)is homogeneous of degree (r − 1) in x for every ` = 1, . . . , L.

Proof: Differentiate with respect to x` the identity that defineshomogeneity of degree r :

G (k x) ≡ k r G (x) ∀k > 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 18 / 49

Page 19: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands (cont’d)

We obtain:

k∂G (k x)

∂x`= k r

∂G (x)

∂x`∀k > 0

or∂G (k x)

∂x`= k(r−1)

∂G (x)

∂x`∀k > 0

This is the definition of homogeneity of degree (r − 1) of the

function∂G (k x)

∂x`.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 19 / 49

Page 20: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Properties of the Conditional Factor Demands (cont’d)

Notice that

6. The Lagrange multiplier of the cost minimization problem isthe marginal cost of output:

∂c(w , y)

∂y= λ(w , y)

Proof: By constrained Envelope Theorem applied to the costfunction:

c(w , y) = w z(w , y)− λ(w , y) [f (z(w , y)− y ]

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 20 / 49

Page 21: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Law of Supply

7. Let the set W of input prices w be open and convex, ifz(w , y) is differentiable in w then:

H =

∂2c∂w2

1· · · ∂2c

∂w1 ∂wh

.... . .

...∂2c

∂wh ∂w1· · · ∂2c

∂w2h

=

∂z1∂w1

· · · ∂z1∂wh

.... . .

...∂zh∂w1

· · · ∂zh∂wh

is a symmetric and negative semi-definite matrix.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 21 / 49

Page 22: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Law of Supply

Proof: Symmetry follows from Shephard’s lemma and YoungTheorem:

∂z`∂wi

=∂

∂wi

(∂c(w , y)

∂w`

)=

∂w`

(∂c(w , y)

∂wi

)=

∂zi∂w`

While negative semi-definiteness follows from the concavity ofc(w , y), the fact that W is open and convex and thefollowing result.

Result

Let F : A→ R where A ⊂ Rn is a convex open set. Let F (·) betwice differentiable. Then the function F (·) is concave if and onlyif the Hessian matrix of F (·) is negative semi-definite on A.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 22 / 49

Page 23: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Euler Theorem

Result (Euler Theorem)

If a function G (x) is homogeneous of degree r in x then:

r G (x) = ∇G (x) x

Proof: Differentiating with respect to k the identity:

G (k x) ≡ k r G (x) ∀k > 0

we obtain:

∇G (kx) x = rk(r−1) G (x) ∀k > 0

for k = 1 we obtain:

∇G (x) x = r G (x).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 23 / 49

Page 24: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale

We now introduce a set of new properties closely related to theones of the expenditure function in consumer theory.

8. If f (x) is homogeneous of degree one (i.e. exhibits constantreturns to scale), then c(w , y) and z(w , y) are homogeneousof degree one in y .

Proof: Let k > 0 and consider:

c(w , k y) = minx

w x

s.t. f (x) ≥ k y(1)

By definition of c(w , y) if x∗ is the solution to the costminimization problem we have y = f (x∗).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 24 / 49

Page 25: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

Hence by homogeneity of degree 1 of f (x) we obtain:

k y = k f (x∗) = f (k x∗)

which implies that k x∗ is feasible in Problem (1).

Therefore:

k c(w , y) = k [w x∗] = w (k x∗) ≥ c(w , k y).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 25 / 49

Page 26: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

Let now x be the solution to Problem (1). Necessarily:f (x) = k y

or, by homogeneity of degree 1:

f [(1/k) x ] = (1/k) f (x) = y

which implies that [(1/k) x ] is feasible in the problem thatdefines c(w , y).

Therefore we get:

c(w , k y) = w x = k w [(1/k) x ] ≥ k c(w , y)

which concludes the proof.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 26 / 49

Page 27: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

8′. In other words, a technology that exhibits CRS has a costfunction that is linear in y : c(w , y) = c(w)y .

9. A technology that exhibits CRS has equal and constantmarginal (∂c(w , y)/∂y) and average cost functions

(∂c(w , y)/∂y) = (c(w , y)/y).

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 27 / 49

Page 28: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

Proof: Homogeneity of degree 1 and Euler theorem imply

cy (w)y = c(w , y) or cy (w) =c(w , y)

y.

-

6 6

-,,,,,,,,,,,,,

y

cy (w) = c(w ,y)y

y

c(w , y) = cy (w) y

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 28 / 49

Page 29: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

10. If f (x) is convex (IRS technology), then the cost functionc(w , y) is concave in y .

11. A technology that exhibits IRS has a decreasing marginal costfunction (∂c(w , y)/∂y) and average cost function

(∂c(w , y)/∂y) ≤ (c(w , y)/y)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 29 / 49

Page 30: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

-

6 6

-

y

c(w ,y)y

y

c(w , y)

cy (w , y)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 30 / 49

Page 31: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

12. If f (x) is concave (DRS technology), then the cost functionc(w , y) is convex in y .

13. A technology that exhibits DRS has an increasing marginalcost function (∂c(w , y)/∂y) and average cost function

(∂c(w , y)/∂y) ≥ (c(w , y)/y)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 31 / 49

Page 32: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Returns to Scale (cont’d)

-

6 6

-

y y

cy (w , y)c(w ,y)

yc(w , y)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 32 / 49

Page 33: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Profit Maximization with Single Output

I Assume that the output market is competitive.

I The profit maximization problem is then:

maxy

p y − c(w , y)

The necessary FOC are:

p − ∂c(w , y∗)

∂y≤ 0

with equality if y∗ > 0.

The sufficient SOC for a local maximum:

∂2c(w , y∗)

∂y2> 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 33 / 49

Page 34: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Profit Maximization with Single Output (cont’d)

I Clearly the SOC imply at least local DRS in a neighborhoodof y∗.

I Notice that if y∗ > 0 the optimal choice of the firm is:

p =∂c(w , y∗)

∂y= MC(y∗)

I In words, price equal to marginal cost.

I This condition defines the solution to the profit maximizationproblem: the supply function: y∗(w , p)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 34 / 49

Page 35: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Profit Maximization with Single Output (cont’d)

The two profit maximization problems we have considered so farproduce the same outcome for equal (w , p).

In fact:maxy

py − c(w , y)

wherec(w , y) = min

xw x

s.t. f (x) ≥ y

yieldsmaxx

p y − w x

s.t. f (x) = y

which is the very first problem we considered.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 35 / 49

Page 36: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run

Short run cost minimization arises when one or more inputs maybe fixed, xh = xh, while the remaining inputs may be varied at will.

The short run variable cost function:

cS(w , y , xh) = wh xh + minx1,...,xh−1

h−1∑`=1

w` x`

s.t. f (x1, . . . , xh−1, xh) ≥ y

Alternatively:

cS(w , y , xh) = minx

w x

s.t. f (x) ≥ y

xh = xh

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 36 / 49

Page 37: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run (cont’d)

If z(w , y) denotes the long run conditional factor demands, thatsolve:

c(w , y) = minx

w x

s.t. f (x) ≥ y

Let x = (x1, . . . , xh) be the input vector that achieves theminimum long run cost of producing y with prices w :

x = (x1, . . . , xh) = z(w , y)

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 37 / 49

Page 38: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run vs. Long Run

We can then characterize the relationship between short and longrun total costs, or alternatively, short run and long run variablecosts (more familiar).

Notice thatc(w , y) ≡ cS(w , y , zh(w , y)) (2)

orc(w , y)

y≡ cS(w , y , zh(w , y))

y

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 38 / 49

Page 39: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont’d)

moreover by Envelope Theorem

∂c(w , y)

∂y≡ ∂cS(w , y , zh(w , y))

∂y(3)

We shall now focus on a neighborhood of (w , y) and setxh = zh(w , y). From (2) above by Envelope Theorem we get:

∂c(w , y)

∂y=∂cS(w , y , xh)

∂y

Recall that Envelope Theorem implies that only the first ordereffect is zero.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 39 / 49

Page 40: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont’d)

Since (3) is an identity in (w , y) we can differentiate both sideswith respect to y :

∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y2+∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y ∂xh

∂zh(w , y)

∂y=∂2c(w , y)

∂y2

and with respect to wh:

∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y ∂wh+∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y ∂xh

∂zh(w , y)

∂wh=∂2c(w , y)

∂y ∂wh

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 40 / 49

Page 41: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont’d)

Now∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y ∂wh= 0

since∂cS(w , y , xh)

∂wh= xh

is independent of y .

Hence by Shephard’s Lemma:

∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y ∂xh=

∂zh(w , y)/∂y

∂zh(w , y)/∂wh

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 41 / 49

Page 42: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont’d)

which implies by substitution:

∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y2+

(∂zh(w , y)/∂y)2

∂zh(w , y)/∂wh=∂2c(w , y)

∂y2

which delivers:

∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y2≥ ∂2c(w , y)

∂y2

since(∂zh(w , y)/∂y)2

∂zh(w , y)/∂wh≤ 0

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 42 / 49

Page 43: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Short Run vs. Long Run (cont’d)

This allows us to conclude that the loss function:

l(w , y) = c(w , y)− cS(w , y , xh) ≤ 0

reaches a local maximum at x .

Proof: We have shown above that the FOC are satisfied:

∂cS(w , y , xh)

∂y=∂c(w , y)

∂y

and we just proved that the SOC hold:

∂2c(w , y)

∂y2≤ ∂2cS(w , y , xh)

∂y2

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 43 / 49

Page 44: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Le Chatelier Principle

In other words:c(w , y) ≤ cS(w , y , xh)

A similar approach proves that for every ` ∈ {1, . . . , h}:

0 ≥∂zS`∂w`

≥ ∂z`∂w`

Moving to profit maximization:

0 ≥∂xS`∂w`

≥ ∂x`∂w`

and

0 ≤ ∂yS

∂p≤ ∂y

∂p

All these results are known as Le Chatelier Principle.Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 44 / 49

Page 45: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Aggregation

I The question we address is when can we speak of anaggregate supply function in similar terms as the aggregatedemand you have seen before?

I The question above is closely related to the question: underwhich conditions can we speak of a representative producer?

I Recall that the key problem when constructing an aggregatedemand was the presence of income effects in consumertheory.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 45 / 49

Page 46: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Aggregate Supply

I The absence of a budget constraint implies that individualfirms’ supply are not subject to income effects.

I Hence aggregation of production theory is simpler andrequires less restrictive conditions.

I Consider J production technologies: (Z 1, . . . ,Z J)

I Let z j(p,w) =

(−x j(p,w)y j(p,w)

)be firm j ’s production plan.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 46 / 49

Page 47: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Law of Supply

I We have seen that the matrix of cross and own price effects ofproduction plan z j(p.w):

Dz j(p,w)

is symmetric and positive semi-definite.

I This is also known as law of supply.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 47 / 49

Page 48: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Aggregate Law of Supply

I Define now the following aggregate optimal production plan:

z(p,w) =J∑

j=1

z j(p,w) =

(−∑

j xj(p,w)∑

j yj(p,w)

)

I Does an aggregate law of supply hold?

I Since both symmetry and positive semi-definiteness arepreserved under sum then

Dz(p,w)

is also symmetric and positive semi-definite.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 48 / 49

Page 49: EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teach/EC487 Slides Lecture 2.pdfEC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2 ... EC487 Advanced Microeconomics,

Representative Producer

Result

In a purely competitive environment the maximum profit obtainedby every firm maximizing profits separately is the same as theprofit obtained if all J firms where they coordinate their choices ina joint profit maximization:

π(p,w) =J∑

j=1

πj(p,w)

In other words, there exists a representative producer.

Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I 6 October, 2017 49 / 49