Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf ·...

30
Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Differential Equations of Mixed Type Hermen Jan Hupkes (Joint work with S.M. Verduyn Lunel) Universiteit Leiden – Typeset by Foil T E X 1

Transcript of Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf ·...

Page 1: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Poitiers 28th June 2006

Center Manifold Theory

for Functional Differential Equations

of Mixed Type

Hermen Jan Hupkes

(Joint work with S.M. Verduyn Lunel)

Universiteit Leiden

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 1

Page 2: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Mixed Type Functional Differential Equations(MFDE)

We are interested in nonlinear differential equations of the form

x(t) = G(xt).

• x is a continuous function with x(t) ∈ R.• xt ∈ C([−1, 1]) is the state of x at t, i.e.,

xt(θ) = x(t+ θ), θ ∈ [−1, 1] .

• G : C([−1, 1])→ R is sufficiently smooth.

Note that

• x(t) depends on both past and future values of x.

• We will look for x(t) near equilibria x, G(x) = 0.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 2

Page 3: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Results

Starting point is the MFDE

x(t) = Lxt +R(xt).

• xt ∈ X = C([−1, 1]) is the state of x at t.

• L : X → R is (for example) the linear operator

φ 7→ A0φ(0) +A−φ(−1) +A+φ(+1).

• R : X → R is a nonlinear smooth operator with R(0) = 0and DR(0) = 0.

Characteristic equation given by ∆(z) = 0, with

∆(z) = z −A0 −A−e−z −A+ez.

We are specially interested in cases where there are eigenvalueson the imaginary axis, i.e., ∆(iω) = 0 for some ω ∈ R.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 3

Page 4: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Results II

Recall

x(t) = Lxt +R(xt). (1)

As for delay equations, can define spectral projectionQ0 : X → X0 ⊂ X onto finite dimensional subspace X0

spanned by elements of the form

φ : t 7→ tleiωt with ∆(iω) = 0 and φ(t) = Lφt.

Main result gives ”smooth” u∗ : X0 →⋂η>0BC

1η such that

(i) Sufficiently small solutions x to (1) are captured viax = u∗(Q0x0).

(ii) Any φ ∈ X0 such that u∗φ is sufficiently small, yields asolution x = u∗φ to (1).

(iii) Dynamics on X0 is captured by ODE (with A = L|X0)

Φ(t) = AΦ(t) + f(Φ(t)), where

f(ψ) = Q0[L(u∗ψ − ψ)θ +R((u∗ψ)θ)].

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 4

Page 5: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

MFDE

Weird ”interaction from future” often raises doubts aboutusefullness of MFDE in modelling applications.

• Lattice differential equations.

One studies travelling wave solutions to infinite dimensionaldifferential systems on discrete lattices.

– Material science (crystals)– Image processing (recognizing edges / outlines in pictures)– Biology (signal propagation through nerves with discrete

gaps)

• Solving optimal control problems with delays.

• Direct models that, indeed, contain past + future terms.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 5

Page 6: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Modelling

Ferdinand Banks in ’Energy Economics: a modern introduction’

The difference between science and economics isthat science aims at the understanding of thebehaviour of nature, while economics is involvedwith an understanding of models- and many ofthese models have no relation to any stateof nature that has ever existed on this planet [...]

Our examples will come from economics.

• Optimal control capital dynamics with delay

• Direct life cycle model

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 6

Page 7: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Optimal Control Capital Market Dynamics

Consider an economy that starts at time t = 0. Total amountof capital in economy given by k(t) ≥ 0. Investments given byu(t).

Production takes time! (Rustichini, 1989)

Consumption c(t) that is technologically feasible depends oninvestments and available capital, i.e.,c(t) = C(u(t− τ), k(t− τ)).

Total welfare is given by ln c(t) > 0 to ensure ”spreading out”of consumption.

Optimal control problem: maximize∫ ∞0

e−ρt lnC(u(t− τ), k(t− τ)

)dt,

subject to k(t) = u(t− τ)− gk(t− τ).

Here g is a form of capital decay rate and ρ is the discountrate. This is a factor to correct for the fact that future welfareis rated to be less important than present welfare.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 7

Page 8: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Euler Lagrange with Delays

Consider the problem to maximize the functional

J(y) =∫ ∞

0

f(t, y(t− τ), y(t), y(t− τ), y(t))dt.

Introduce notation x(t) = y(t− τ) and z(t) = y(t+ τ).

Theorem 1 (Hughes 1968). If y maximizes J , then thefollowing MFDE is satisfied

D3︸︷︷︸y(t)

f(t, x, y, x, y) + D2︸︷︷︸y(t−τ)

f(t+ τ, y, z, y, z)

= (d/dt)[ D5︸︷︷︸y(t)

f(t, x, y, x, y)

+ D4︸︷︷︸y(t−τ)

f(t+ τ, y, z, y, z)].

• Solving an optimal control problem with delays thus leads toa MFDE!

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 8

Page 9: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Market Dynamics with Delays

Application of Hughes’ result to maximize∫ ∞0

e−ρt lnC(u(t− τ), k(t− τ)

)dt,

leads to MFDE

e−ρ(t+τ)[gD1C/C +D2C/C](k(t+ τ) + gk(t), k(t)

)= d

dt

(e−ρtD1C/C(k(t) + gk(t− τ), k(t− τ))

).

(2)

Our example: C(u, k) =√u− k. Steady state solution

k =e−2ρτ

4(ρ+ ge−ρτ)2.

Linearizing around steady state and trying exponential solutionsezt yields characteristic equation

∆(z) = (z − ρe−(z−ρ)τ)(z − ρ+ ρezτ)−1

2(ρ+ ge−ρτ)(2ρeρτ + g) = 0.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 9

Page 10: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Market Dynamics with Delay

• Benhabib & Nishimura (1979) analyzed model withoutdelays, but with at least three different economic goods.

• They found a pair of distinct eigenvalues that cross theimaginary axis when varying the parameters (ρ, g), leading toHopf bifurcation.

• Using CM reduction we are able to do the same for MFDE.

• ∆(z) is transcendental function with infinitely many zeroesto the right and left of imaginary axis.

• Numerically study zeroes in a neighbourhood of origin.

• Economically interesting periodic solutions for models withonly one production and one consumption good.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 10

Page 11: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Zeroes

Roots of ∆(z) in rectangle [−5, 5]× [−23, 23], calculated usingcomplex bisection.

-0.4 -0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

Im z

Re z

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 11

Page 12: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Zeroes - Detail

� ������� ������ �������� �������� ������ � !�"�#%$ &�'�( ) *�+�,�- .�/�0�1 2�3�4�5 6�7�8�9:<;>=

?<@>A

BDCFE

G

HFI

J>K

L>M

N O PRQTSVUXWY Z [R\T]_^a`b c dfehgViXjkml

n

oqp r

Observe crossing of imaginary axis at g ≈ 13.667698, ρ = 0.80,τ = 4.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 12

Page 13: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Hopf bifurcation

Periodic solutions were computed for capital k(t).

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.01.4

1.6

1.8

2.0

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3.0

3.2

3.4

3.6 g = 13.60 g = 13.63 g = 13.65 g = 13.66 g = 13.665 g = 13.6673

104 k

(t)

t/T

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

g = 10.00 g = 11.00 g = 12.00 g = 13.00 g = 13.50

104 k

(t)

t/T

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 13

Page 14: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Hopf bifurcation

Using computed periodic solutions, can construct localbifurcation diagram.

9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 190

5

10

15

20

equilibrium

Hopf bifurcation

min

/ m

ax o

rbit

g

Explicit formula available for computing direction of bifurcation,derived by ”lifting” finite dimensional Hopf bifurcation on CM.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 14

Page 15: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Direct modelling: Life cycle model

Albis et al. (2004) consider a population model consisting ofoverlapping generations, that leads directly to MFDE.

• Fixed size population normalized to one. Each individuallives for time T = 1.

• Individuals born at time s have assets a(s, t) at time t.

• At birth, assets are zero, i.e., a(s, s) = 0.

• One does not die in debt, i.e., a(s, s+ 1) ≥ 0.

• Age-independent wages w(t) are received.

• Interest rate r(t).

• Individuals born at time s consume c(s, t) at time t.

Individual budget constraint:

∂a(s, t)∂t

= r(t)a(s, t) + w(t)− c(s, t).

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 15

Page 16: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Life cycle model II

Goal of every individual born at time s is to maximize hislifetime welfare, given by

∫ s+1

s

ln c(s, τ)dτ.

Solving this optimization problem shows that the optimal assetdistribution a∗(s, t) depends on the interest rates and wagesduring the lifetime of an individual, i.e.,

a∗(s, t) = F (rs+, ws+, t− s),

for some F . Here rs+ ∈ C([0, 1]) is defined byrs+(θ) = r(s+ θ).

The total amount of capital at any time t is given by

k(t) =∫ t

t−1

a∗(σ, t)dσ,

namely the total amount of assets owned by living individuals.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 16

Page 17: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Life cycle model III

The economy has a single market good, that can be used forboth production and consumption. It is produced at the rate Qgiven by

Q(k(t), e(t), l(t)) = Ak(t)α(e(t)l(t))β.

• l(t) is the labour supply, in our case l(t) = 1.• e(t) accounts for the increase in labour efficiency over time.• A,α, β > 0 are parameters.• Q above is known as a Cobb-Douglas production function.

Note that interest rate r(t) is, (by definition), the price ofcapital. Similarly, the wages w(t) are the price of labour. Theycan be found by partial differentiation of Q.

r(t) = ∂Q∂k = αAk(t)α−1(e(t)l(t))β,

w(t) = ∂Q∂l = βAk(t)αe(t)βl(t)β−1.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 17

Page 18: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Life cycle model IV

We can now put everything back together.

k(t) =∫ tt−1

a∗(σ, t)dσ,

a∗(s, t) = F (rs+, ws+, t− s),

r(t) = ∂Q∂k = αAk(t)α−1(e(t)l(t))β,

w(t) = ∂Q∂l = βAk(t)αe(t)βl(t)β−1.

Substituting everything into the first equation, we arrive at

k(t) = G(kt, α, β),

in which kt ∈ C([−1, 1]) is given by kt(θ) = k(t+ θ).

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 18

Page 19: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Life cycle model V

Threefold differentiation of

k(t) = G(kt, α, β). (3)

using the explicit form of G yields an MFDE

k′′′(t) = f(k(t), k′(t), k′′(t), k(t− 1), k(t+ 1),∫ t+1

tk(τ)α+β−1dτ,

∫ t−1

tk(τ)α+β−1dτ).

(4)

Albis et al. choose α+ β = 1, in which case the MFDEbecomes linear.

We are interested in α+ β 6= 1, and we find that for everyγ = α+ β 6= 1, (4) has a unique strictly positive equilibriumsolution k.

Linearization around k yields the characteristic equation with

w = αAkγ−1

,

∆(z + w) = αz3 + w(α− γ2)z2 − γw2(1− γ)z− wγ((γ − 1)w2 + 2β)+ (z + w)−1[2βw(γz + w) cosh z+

w2(γ − 1)(γw2 + 2β)].

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 19

Page 20: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Life cycle model VI

Roots of ∆(z) with α = β.

-15 -10 -5 0 5 10 15

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

α = 0.11 α = 0.22 α = 0.33 α = 0.44 α = 0.55 α = 0.66 α = 0.77 α = 0.88

Im z

Re z

• Real root crosses the imaginary axis at α+ β = 1• Apparently no imaginary pair of roots that cross imaginary

axis.• Since we demand k > 0, eigenmodes with Re z > 0 and

Im z 6= 0 do not interest us.• Loss of stability when α+ β > 1?

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 20

Page 21: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Recent Model (Albis et al. 2005)

Similar model, now with fixed wages only in the time periode[α, 1− α] ⊂ [0, 1] of an individual’s life.

Albis et al. attempt to find Hopf bifurcations for characteristicequation

∆(z) = −∫ 1−αα

ezτdτ

1− 2α+ (1− σ)

∫ 1

0

ezτdτ +σ∫ 1

0e−zτdτ

.

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5

-20

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

σ = 0.02 σ = 0.06 σ = 0.10 σ = 0.14 σ = 0.18 σ = 0.22 σ = 0.26 σ = 0.30 σ = 0.315 σ = 0.321 σ = 0.3225 σ = 0.325

Im z

Re z

Fixed α = 0.2. Conditions for Hopf bifurcation not satisfied!

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 21

Page 22: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

The program

• Analyze the linear homogeneous equation

x(ξ) = Lxξ

and determine set N0 of solutions that grow at mostpolynomially.• Analyze the linear inhomogeneous equation

x(ξ) = Lxξ + f(ξ) (5)

and find an ”inverse” K such that x = Kf solves (5) and Kprojects out N0 in some sense.• Analyze functional

G(u, y) = y +K(R(u)),

for y ∈ N0. Use fixpoint arguments to find fixpoint u(y) forG(·, y) for sufficiently small y. Note that u(y) solves

x(ξ) = Lxξ +R(xξ).

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 22

Page 23: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Comparison with delay equations

The homogeneous linear equation

x(ξ) = Lxξ,

is for general MFDE not a well-posed initial value problem, ifwe demand x continuous.

Example: x|[−1,1] = 1 and

x′(ξ) = x(ξ − 1) + x(ξ + 1).

���

��������

��� ������������������

"! #%$

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 23

Page 24: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Comparison with delay equations II

Linear delay equations (RFDE) however do allow uniqueforward continuation of solutions, i.e., the problem

x(ξ) = Ldxξ−, x0− = φ,

in which xξ− ∈ C([−1, 0]) is defined by xξ−(θ) = x(ξ + θ), hassolution

xt− = S(t)φ,

in which S(t) is an eventually compact semigroup, withgenerator

A : D(A) = {φ ∈ C1([−1, 0]) | φ(0) = Ldφ} → C([−1, 0])Aφ = φ

One can thus employ all the strong results from semigrouptheory, in particular variation of constants formula!

As in study of elliptic PDEs (Mielke, Kirchgassner), need toconstruct pseudo inverse K by hand for MFDE.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 24

Page 25: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Linear inhomogeneous equations

The important step is to analyze the linear inhomogeneousequation

x(ξ) = Lxξ + f(ξ), (6)

for functions f : R→ R.

Mallet-Paret established result for hyperbolic versions of (6),using Laplace transform techniques.

Theorem 2. Suppose that ∆(z) = 0 has no roots on theimaginary axis. Then for every f ∈ L∞, (6) has a uniquesolution in W 1,∞, given by

x(ξ) =∫ ∞−∞

G(ξ − s)f(s)ds,

where G has Fourier transform G(η) = ∆(iη)−1.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 25

Page 26: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Nonhyperbolic inhomogeneous equations

However, when we have spectrum on the imaginary axis,

x(ξ) = Lxξ

has set of solutions N0 that are bounded or grow at most at apolynomial rate. Need to find a ”pseudo-inverse” that projectsout these solutions in some way.

Want to apply Mallet-Paret theorem, but need to ”shift” theeigenvalues off the imaginary axis first.

This can be done by multiplying the equations withexponentials eηξ.

Laplace transform enables us to link the ”projecting out” ofsolutions in N0, to the projection Q0 onto the spectralsubspace X0.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 26

Page 27: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Dynamics on the Center Manifold

For any φ ∈ X0, define the function Φ : R→ X0 by

Φ(t) = Q0[(u∗φ)t].

Then Φ satisfies an ODE on the center manifold

Φ(ξ) = AΦ(ξ) + f(Φ(ξ)), where

f(ψ) = Q0[L(u∗ψ − ψ)θ + R((u∗ψ)θ)].(7)

Here R is ”cut-off” version of R, i.e., globally bounded.Conversely, if Ψ satisfies (7), then x = u∗Ψ(0) satisfies

x(t) = Lxt + R(xt)

and in addition, xt = (u∗Ψ(t))0.

For delay eqs. (RFDE), variation of constants approach yields

fd(ψ) = Q0[R((u∗ψ)0)δ(θ)].

Although this appears to differ from (7), examples indicate thatour f restricted to RFDE yields same Taylor expansions as fd.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 27

Page 28: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

Further issues

• In the context of RFDE, one can also study invariant stableand unstable manifolds that capture sufficiently smallsolutions on the halflines R±.

• This feature is absent from our analysis here, due to theill-posedness of the initial value problem. We cannot define asuitable solution operator for linear systems on half lines.

• Mallet - Paret and Verduyn Lunel (2001) have some resultsin this direction

• Need to develop Floquet theory to analyze periodic solutionsof MFDE.

• Need to do some work on stability analysis. Spectrum isunbounded to the left and right of imaginary axis. Butperhaps results restricted to positive solutions? Useful formodelling applications.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 28

Page 29: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

References

• d’Albis, H. and Augeraud-Veron, E. (2004), CompetitiveGrowth in a Life-Cycle Model: Existence and Dynamics.Preprint.• d’Albis, H. and Augeraud-Veron, E. (2005), Balanced Cycles

in an OLG Model with a Continuum of Finitely-LivedIndividuals. Preprint.• Benhabib, J. and Nishimura, K. (1979), The Hopf

Bifurcation and the Existence and Stability of Closed Orbitsin Multisector Models of Optimal Economic Growth. J.Econ. Theory 21, 421-444.• Diekmann, O., van Gils, S.A., Verduyn-Lunel, S.M. and

Walther, H.O. (1995), Delay Equations. Springer-Verlag,New York.• J. Harterich, B. Sandstede and A. Scheel (2002),

Exponential Dichotomies for Linear Non-Autonomousfunctional differential equations of Mixed Type. IndianaUniv. Math. J. 51, 1081-1109.• Hughes, D.K. (1968), Variational and Optimal Control

Problems with Delayed Argument. J. of Optimization Th.and Appl. 2, 1-14.• Hupkes, H.J. and Verduyn-Lunel, S.M. (2005), Analysis of

Newton’s Method to Compute Travelling Waves in DiscreteMedia. J. Dyn. Diff. Eqn. 17, 523-572.• Hupkes, H.J. and Verduyn-Lunel, S.M. (2006), Center

Manifold Theory for Functional Differential Equations ofMixed Type. Submitted to J. Dyn. Diff. Eqn. MI 2006-03.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 29

Page 30: Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential Equations of …hhupkes/poitiers_talk.pdf · 2006. 6. 23. · Poitiers 28th June 2006 Center Manifold Theory for Functional Di erential

• Mallet-Paret, J. (1999), The Fredholm Alternative forFunctional Differential Equations of Mixed Type. J. Dyn.Diff. Eqn. 11, 1-48.• Mallet-Paret, J. and Verduyn-Lunel, S.M. (2001),

Exponential dichotomies and Wiener-Hopf factorizations formixed-type functional differntial equations To appear in J.Diff. Eqn. MI 2001-17.• Rustichini, A. (1989), Hopf Bifurcation for

Functional-Differential Equations of Mixed Type. J. Dyn.Diff. Eqn. 1, 145-177.

– Typeset by FoilTEX – 30