‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the...

146
^ ѣ ' i i / t ·< i ГТ \ ( . j -,-'ί í ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І li ¡ 1 Гй, "TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 - A

Transcript of ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the...

Page 1: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

^ ѣ ' i i / t ·< i ГТ \ ■( . j -,-'ί í‘ . - w * ЧІ І І l i ¡ 1 Гй, "TT o i /ІА i i H i/i.

'i 7-50 -

A

Page 2: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

BREAD AND PROVISIONING IN THE OTTOMAN EMPIRE:1750-1860

A THESIS PRESENTED BY IKLIL EREFETO

THE INSTITUTE OF ECONOMICS AND SOCIAL SCIENCES IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE

REQUIREMENTSFOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF

HISTORY

i k h l

BILKENT UNIVERSITY AUGUST,1997

Page 3: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

НС^ 9 2

ß . с :ΐ R R О 8

Page 4: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

I certify that I have read tliis thesis and in my opinion it is flilly adequate,

in sco p e and quality, as a thesis for the d eg ree o f m aste r o f H istory .

Thesis Supervisor Prof. D r. H alil İn a lc ık

T certify tha t I have read this thesis and in m y opin ion it is fully ad eq u a te ,

in scope and quality, as a thesis for the degree of master of History,

Dr. S. Ak§in Somel

/

I certify that I have read this thesis and in my opinion it is fully adequate,

in scope and quality, as a thesis for the degree o f master o f History.

Dr. Melunet Kalpaklı

Approved by The Institute of Economics and Social Sciences

Prof. Dr. Ali Karaosmanoglu

Page 5: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

ABSTRACT

The study examines bread and the provisioning question in the Ottoman Empire during

the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, Wheat and bread supply o f the most important

center of the Empire: Istanbul is focused on. In this context, Ottoman State's

intervention in the economy and its motivation to do so is analyzed. I argue that the

Ottoman government had a pragmatic motivation in interfering with provisioning,

beginning from the cultivation of grain, up to distribution o f bread to the consumers.

The analysis is made using archival sources and published primary sources. Kadi court

records, published state records, documents of the Cevdet Belediye and Mühimme

classifications of the Başbakanlık Cumhuriyet archives are among these documents. In

the study it is suggested that production of bread which was the basic source of

nourishment with an additional symbolically 'sacred' character, was subject to close

control of the government. State control is observable in the transportation,

requisition, storage, and the distribution of wheat as welt as in the monopolies o f

bakers, and the rules of market regulation imposed by state officials

Page 6: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

ÖZET

Bu araştırmada 18. ve 19. yüzyıllarda Osmanlı İmparatorluğu'nun iaşesi ve ekmek

sorunsalı İncelenmektedir. İmparatorluğun en önemli merkezi olan İstanbul'un buğday

ve ekmek ihtiyacının karşılanması konusuna değinilmektedir. Bu bağlamda, Osmanlı

Devleti'nin ekonomiye müdahalesi ve bu konudaki motivasyonu ele alınmaktadır.

Araştırmalarıma göre Osmanlı hükümeti iaşe konusunda hububat ekiminden tüketiciye

ekmek dağıtımına kadar müdahalesinde pragmatik bir yaklaşıma sahipti. Çalışmamda

arşiv belgeleri ve yayınlanmış birinci el kaynaklar kullanılmıştır. Bu belgeler, kadı

sicilleri, yayınlanmış devlet kayıtları ile Başbakanlık Cumhuriyet arşivleri Cevdet

Belediye ve Mühimme tasniflerine ait kayıtlardır. İncelememde, sembolik bir kutsallığa

sahip olan, aynı zamanda temel besin maddesi olan ekmeğin yakın devlet takibi altında

bulunduğu öne sürülmektedir. Devlet kontrolü, buğdayın taşınması, satın alınması,

stoklanması, dağıtımı; ekmek üreticilerinin tekeli ve devletin memurları tarafından

gerçekleştirilen pazar kontrolünde görülmektedir.

Page 7: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

To ту grandmother Cihadiye Erefe

Ш

Page 8: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

I would like to express my gratitude to my family who showed great patience

and provided me with the moral support to complete this study. I am grateful to my

supervisor Professor Halil İnalcık for his indispensable guidance and his permission to

use documents of the İnalcık Collection. I am also grateful to Professor Özer Ergenç

for his moral support, technical help and for the kadi sicils he showed me. i would like

to thank my Professors Suraiya Faroqhi and Huricihan İslamoğlu lor introducing me to

Ottoman studies and encouraging me to continue with graduate study. I am grateful to

Professor Eyüp Özveren for his support. I would also like to thank my professors

Mehmet Kalpaklı, Akşin Somel, Yılmaz Kurt, Necdet Gök and Eftal Batmaz for their

help and encouragement.

I would especially like to thank my house-mate Mahmut and the Yüksel

Family. I am greatly indebted to Ali Yaycıoğlu and his family. My special thanks go to

my friends Berrak Burçak, Latif Armağan, Bekir Koç, Dritan Egro, Pınar Emiralioğlu,

Bahadır Koç, Fehmi Yılmaz, Bora Nalbantoğlu, Özgür Yanık, Tolga Bölükbaşı, and to

Başak Yüksel and Ebru Bodur for everything from the beginning.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

IV

Page 9: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

CONTENTS

AbstractÖzetAcknowledgment s Table of Contents List of Abbreviations

1

iiiiiivV

INTRODUCTION

Ottoman Artisanal Organization: The Question of Autonomy

Outline of Study

111

CHAPTER I: The question of Provisioning

1.1 State Policy

1.2 Grain Transport by the Government: Dealing with Contraband Trade

1.3 Storage

1.4 Unkapani

1.5 Conclusion

14

17

25

28

30

CHAPTER II: Quality and Price Inspection (iHTISAB)

3.1 Application in 'Bread'

3.2 The Fiscal Sphere-Taxation

3.3 Conclusion.

53

70

72

CONCLUSION

APPENDIX I: Tatarcık Abdullah Ağa Report

APPENDIX II: Religious Functions of the Muhtesib

GLOSSARY

BIBLIOGRAPHY

PHOTOCOPIES OF ARCHIVAL MATERIAL USED

74

79

82

84

86

93

Page 10: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

LIST OF ABBREVIA TIONS

ACR Ankara Kadi Court Records

AO Archivum Ottomanicum

AÜDTCF Ankara Üniversitesi Dil ve Tarih-Coğrafya Fakültesi

BCR Bursa Kadı Court Records

CB Cevdet Belediyye

DHBD Divan-ı Humayun Buyıuldu Defteri

DHED Divan-ı Humayun Esnaf Defteri

DHİD Divan-ı Humayun İstanbul Defteri

E12 Encyclopedia o f İslam Second Edition

UTS International Journal o f Turkish Studies

IJMES International Journal o f Middle Eastern Studies

ICR Istanbul Kadi Court Records

iF M Istanbul Üniversitesi İktisat Fakültesi Mecmuası

İÜEFSD İstanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi Sosyoloji Dergisi

JEEH Journal o f European Economic Histoıy

JEH Journal o f Economic History

M D Mühimme Defteri

SEHME Studies on the Economic History o f the Middle East

TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi

TOEM Tarih-i Osmani Encümeni Mecmuası

TV Tarih Vesikaları

VI

Page 11: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

INTRODUCTION

Ottoman Artisanal Organization: The question o f Autonomy

Studies on the Ottoman State in relation to the pre-capitalist economy;

considerations of the legal regulation of the economy have displayed the framework o f

an "economic mind" encompassing fiscalist, provisionalist, traditionalist and anti­

mercantilist measures. Ottoman economy had an emphasis on plenty as opposed to

windfall profits that could be accrued out of business, or revenue out of exports.

Ottoman State's intervention in the economy took place in the forms of controlling

market prices, the quality of goods sold, determining monopolies o f necessities and

regulating guilds and customs.’ State intervention was percieved as a tool that

protected revenue sources of the treasuiy . and the interests o f both producers and

consumers Crafts production and artisans' organization have stood out as important

components of this structure.^ Various approaches of research into Ottoman History-

have had their reflections in this field, as well. Below is an attempt to view different

approaches and their impacts on considerations of Ottoman artisanal organization in

relation to the Ottoman State.

Crafts guilds have often been considered to be special organizations through

which state intervention over the economy was reassured. This approach can be

characterized by the "institutionalist" or "statutary" perspective reflected in the work of

Gabriel Baer on Ottoman guilds. Baer has asserted that until the fifteenth century,

'Halil İnalcık (1994). Ed. with D. Quataert, An Economic and Social History o f the Ottoman Empire, 1300-1914, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge: 51.

"İnalcık with Quataert (1994): 53.

^İnalcık (1970). "Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects of the Ottoman Economy." in Economic History o f the Middle East, ed. M. A. Cook, Oxford Universiri Press, London: 207-218.

Page 12: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

there were no guilds in Anatolia and the Ahi* gatherings constituted a non-professional

organization. By the seventeenth century, however, according to Baer, some scholars

put forward that the entire population came to be included in the guild system. Evliya

Çelebi's description of the guilds' muster by Murad IV^ reflects the wide inclusion to

the guild organization. Baer has interpreted this picture by differentiating between the

guild members. This differentiation is inherent in his grouping. One group includes all

urban population except higher bureaucracy and the army, while the other group

includes artisans and merchants, guilds of transport and services, and finally, guilds

connected with medicine.^ This analysis on the functions of Ottoman guilds has been

primarily based on Osman Nuri Ergin's Mecelle-i Umur-i Belediyye. Baer's approach

emphasizes the institutional structure of guilds in wliich, guilds are mentioned, to begin

with, as an administrative link between the state and the urban population.’ In this

framework, the guild kedbüdâ was the representative of the guild before the

government authorities, as well as that of the authorites before the guild. Baer's

suggestion concerning this issue is that the kethüda was for the most part, a

government agent, rather than the spokesman of the guild. *

Concerning the taxation o f guilds, Baer has stated that Turkish guilds had no

fiscal functions and these functions were among the duties of the mubtesib. Some

exceptions are mentioned by Baer including the responsibility of some kcthiidas for the

payment o f custom dues o f some products. The quality control of products; weights

''Professional organization of Anatolian craftsmen around the ethics of “futii\"vet” (ftituwwa).

^Evliya Çelebi Seyahatnamesi (1914), Vol. I, Istanbul: 512-669 cited by Gabriel Baer ( 1970), "The administrative, Economic and Social functions of Turkish Guilds," IJMES, I-l: 30.

®Baer(1970); 31-32.

■'ibid. : 33.

Page 13: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

and measures have been viewed by Baer as an area of state regulation within which

guilds were used as an instrument for the supervision of regulatory instructions.^ In

other words, guilds' control over the quality of goods was limited, and in the last

resort, effective measures of regulation were taken by the kadi}'^ Fixing prices and

wages have been viewed in a similar context, attributing a relatively passive position to

the guilds and emphasizing government control, Other basic functions of guilds have

been summarized as: provision of the army with services and labor as auxiliaries

{orducu) in times of war;" The supply and distribution of goods to the authorities as

well as the supply and distribution of raw materials to the artisans." Moreover, guilds

carried out the function of arbitrating disputes among their members and provision of

mutual help.*' One effective function of Turkish guilds was the tdaviin sandığı or

esnafın orta sandığı which allowed artisans to arrange mutual help for their members.

Important disputes among craftsmen were either heard at the court of kadi, or were

handled by the muhtesib. In this field, again, a significant level of autonomy had been

exceptionally granted only to the guild of shoe-makers, allowing them the exemption

from the jurisdiction o f government officers

The above mentioned institutionalist analysis has been subject to criticisms.

Some scholars have asserted that such views of historians assuming a dominant

character for the Ottoman State over all other smaller institutions of the empire was a

mere adoption of the viewpoint o f the Ottoman ruling class. This view, involved the

%id. : 35.

’ ibid, : 36.

’’Ibid. : 37-38.

"Ibid. : 40.

’-Ibid. : 41-42.

Page 14: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

perception of sixteenth century Ottoman Empire to epitomize the ideal militarized

state. This ideal establishment was able to manipulate artisans and peasants in a desired

fashion, without drawing significant reaction. As opposed to this argument, Suraiya

Faroqhi points at reactions o f Istanbul's craftsmen who refused to work unless their

demands for higher wages were accepted, in 1580.*’ She also asserts that craftsmen

identified with the system of market controls and at times, they complained from

merchants, from rival guilds and other competitors whenever their interests were

concerned. They demanded the support of the state against rivalry and the profiteering

activities of merchants. *’ According to this perspective, considering the practice of

"orducu", within the institutionalist perspective as adopted by Gabriel Baer, artisans

were studied as "servants of the war machine",*^ Therefore, perception of guilds

merely as an instrument of the state, is not a fair assessment. Faroqhi refers to Halil

inalcik's analysis on the kethüda appointment, asserting that the selection of the

candidate by the guildsmen, a transfer of office from one incumbent to the next

including a payment o f money, and the approval o f the state, displayed a complex

structure of the guild system as a whole

In fact, inalcik's works on Ottoman economy in general and those on urban

production, trade and the agents involved in this structure in particular, have

'^Ibid, : 42.'^Suraiya Faroqhi 'The fieldglass and the Magnifying Lens: Studies of Ottoman Crafts and Craftsmen,” JEEH,: 42 referring to Ö. L. Barkan’s (1949-1950). “ Osmanh İmparatorluğunda Bir İskan ve Kolonizas>on Metodu Olarak Sürgünler,"/FA/, 11, 1-4:545.

'^Barkan ( 1972/1979) Süleymaniye Cami ve İmareti İnşaat (1550-1557), 2 vols. , Ankara: 292 cited by Faroqhi: 42,

'^Faroqlii: 43.

' "Gabriel Baer (1970) “The Administrative, Economic and Social Functions of Turkish Guilds,” IJMES, 28-50, cited by Faroqhi: 44.

Page 15: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

constmcted a wholistic picture related to the above-mentioned problematic.'* Before

going into details of contemporary discussions, it is necessaiy to analyze İnalcık's

works on Ottoman economy which have depended on archival documents, therefore

have enabled the formation o f a solid ground of scrutiny.

İnalcık has pointed at a significant autonomy level o f Ottoman guilds as

opposed to Gabriel Baer's interpretation o f guilds as 'institutions under strict state

control imposed via the kethüda’. The internal organisation of Ottoman artisans

consisted o f a limited number o f usías (master craftsmen). Among these ustas, a

council o f six (altılar) was elected which included the şeyh (the religious head), the

kethüda, the yiğitbaşı (who was responsible for the administration of the internal

affairs of the guild), işçi-haşı, and two artisans. I'he duties of this council were, to

control the quality o f goods produced, to carry out the examinations of promotion

from apprentice to journeyman and from journeyman to master, and to issue their

icazes (licences); to settle disputes and prevent malpractices in the guild; to represent

the guild before the government; to prevent competition and illegal practices in buying

stocks and employing w o r k e r s . T h e nature and the degree of state involvement in this

organisation can be detected by looking at İnalcık's analysis of the kethüda

appointment:

' İnalcık withQuataert (1994): 44-54, 179-187, 256-269. 271-311; İnalcık (1994) The Ottoman Empire, the Classical Age, 1300-1600, Phoenix, London; İnalcık (1980). "The Hub of the City: The Bedestan of İstanbul," UTS, 1: 1-17; İnalcık (1970). "The Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects of the Ottoman Economy," SEHME, ed. M.A Cook, O.\ford University Press, London: 207-218; İnalcık (1985). "Military and Fiscal Transformation of the Ottoman Empire, \(>00-\100,”SOESH, Vaiorum Reprints, London.

'^Halil İnalcık (1970): 216.

Page 16: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

This analysis o f a document dated 25 Rabi' 1145^^ displays that the

appointment o f kethüda was carried out according to a routine bureaucratic

procedure.^' This procedure began with a recommendation made by a responsible

official, supporting the interested party (or the candidate). Following this ‘ar^, the

grand vizier instructed scrutiny which was to be made by the concerned government

bureau, Following the completion o f this investigation, and the grand vizier’s order, a

ferman (decree) was issued. The candidate received his 6era7 (diploma) as a result of

this process. The candidate also made a payment to the previous warden in order to be

appointed, which indicates an atmosphere of agreement of the parties.

İnalcık has emphasized the autonomy of Ottoman guilds pointing at the fact

that the candidate- or the subject o f the petition was originally chosen among the guild

members. Therefore, the procedure did not involve a simple appointment by the state,

on the contrary, the state appointed the person who was elected by his peers. The

officer was elected independently. The necessity for recording tins election, or

approving the appointment aroused from the need for state support to be granted to

the officer in times of trouble. The berât of the kethüda proved that he was backed by

sultanic authority, which reaffirmed his power o f successfully exercising his duty. At

the same time, the berät placed the corresponding responsibility on the government

authorities of supporting the kethüda.^“* In order to become an authority in the empire.

İnalcık (1986/1993)" The Appointment Procedure of a Guild Warden (Ketkhuda),” The Middle East and the Balkans Under the Ottoman Empire: Essays on Economy and Society, Indiana: 194-201.

-'İnalcık (1986/1993): 196.

"Ibid. : 197.

-^Ibid,: 197.

-"Ibid.

Page 17: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

as long as the sultan approved its legitimacy by a berät. Since such a dual responsibility

scheme is observed, it is understandable why the candidate is subjected to the initial

scrutiny. Depending on the evidence put forward by İnalcık, it would be appropriate to

say that neither a "totally autonomous" guild picture, nor a "totally dependent"

structure is valid. The kethüda is elected by the guild members. His candidacy is put

forward by way of a recommendation. The situation is investigated by the

government's bureaucratic mechanism and the appointment is complete once the

decree, allowing the nominee to receive his diploma is issued.

Haim Gerber, whose previous work has been for the most part in conformity

with what Gabriel Baer has put forward, following İnalcık's analysis on the kethüda

appointment seems to have changed his point of view concerning the autonomy level

of Ottoman artisans Gerber has claimed that Ottoman guild law was not imposed by a

sacred tradition-from above. This argument has been based İnalcık's article "The

Appointment Procedure of a Guild Warden: Ketkhuda". Gerber has put forward that

Ottoman judicial decisions were made by tracing "past relations and r i g h t s " . T h e

results o f his observations have led to the assertion that guild law was not handed

down by the government, however, it was applied in courts as an imposed law. What

these assertions amount to, is that the guild rules were not strictly imposed by the state

or guilds themselves. The regulations, for the most part, were the continuities o f law

based on custom. This idea is expressed by Gerber as: "Ottoman society was saturated

from top to bottom by a sociopsychological ethos that may be termed a customary law

mentality."

■^Haim Gerber (1994) State, Society and Law in Islam, Ottoman Law in a Comparative Perspective, SUNY Press, NY Albany.

■*Gerber (1994): 114. It should be noted that one must be careful when speaking about “customary law”. İnalcık in his work on Weber and Sultanism has clarified that the state legalized old customs.

Page 18: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

In support of his argument, Gerber refers to the court records o f Bursa,

Ayntab, and to some extent, to those of Istanbul, putting forward the picture of a

heterogeneous guild system immune from uniform and tight government control. In

this framework, eighteenth century Ayntab is said to possess a guild system of free

guild agreement where the production standard was attributed to old custom, rather

than to the government,^’According to these criteria, the economic monopolies upheld

by the guilds were an outgrowth of customary law.^^Guilds' complaints concerning

violations of production originated from disturbances of guilds' own traditional

privileges rather than state laws

The position of state within this framework has been summarized by Gerber as:

"State backed the customaiy law, showed interest in guild affairs especially in those

processing gold and silver; drafted artisans to service in times of war, employed quite a

number of artisans for palace service; used guilds to levy taxes on urban population;

showed interest in fraud on the part of artisans producing basic foodstuffs, "^*^These

areas of interest shown by the state include the regulations o f ihtisab as well as

practices such as orducu çıkarmak ( sending auxiliaries for the provisioning o f the

army) in times of war. Gerber's interpretation is that these state interventions do not

reflect an interest in regulating the guild system, or the urban adult population.'^' His

argument is premised on the assertion that guilds were not tightly controlled. Another

As put forward by İnalcık, “customaiy law” seems to be a false category which can be corrected as “law based on custom”, since once sanctioned by the sultan, custom became a “law”.

-"Ibid. : 117.

'“Ibid. : 118.

'^Ibid. : 120.

'“Ibid. : 125.

"Ibid.

Page 19: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

claim put forward by Gerber concerns the "loose institutional structure" o f Ankara

guilds. This assertion involves a criticism of Özer Ergenç's comparative work on the

towns of Ankara and Konya o f the Classical Age, where a strict state control via

institutionalization in the society is documented. This criticism amounts to the

conclusion that "The Ottoman approach to civil society fell a great deal short of

Sultanism." It is among Gerber's assertions that this approach concurs with the

conclusion reached by İnalcık in "The Appointment Procedure of a Guild Warden

(kedkhuda)".

On the economic side, similarly, recent research has placed special emphasis on

the restructuring of Turkish guilds in accordance with the commercialization o f the

economy. Suraiya Faroqhi's work on eighteenth century Bursa guilds is another

example where an active character is attributed to Ottoman guilds. In her "Ottoman

Guilds of the Late Eighteenth Century: The Bursa Case," ’ ' Faroqhi refers to two

different evolutions of Turkish guilds that were obser\'able in the eighteenth and

nineteenth centuries. One of these evolution paths has been displayed in the work of

Nicolaj Todorov on nineteenth century Bulgarian gu i lds .Thi s is the case where some

nineteenth century guilds tended to "develop into a manufacturers’ association,"''^ In

fact, the production of cheap woolen cloth by a local family had taken the form of

small scale factory production. This evolution did not involve an abandoning of the

’Mbiil in"SuraİNa Faroqhi (IW.“’) ' ülloinan Guilds in the Late Eighteenth Centur>’: The Bursa Case." Analecta Isisiana Xyill, Making a Living in the Otloman Lands 1480 to 1820, the Isis Press, Istanbul,

93 * 112 .

■’Nikolay Todorov (1967-68) “ !9.cu Yiizytltn tik yanstnda Bulgaristan Esnaf Teşkilatında Bazı Karakter Değişmeleri," İFM, 27, 1-2: 1-36 ; Ntcolaj Todorov (1980), Lo ville Balkanique aux XJ e- XlXe siècles, Développement socio-économique et démographique. Bucharest, cited by Faroqhi (1995) : 94.

.1.1·Faroqhi (1995). : 94,

Page 20: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

guilds, however it was realized by taking over guild offices and controlling them. The

related area had been selected by Sultan Mahmud II to provide Asakir-i M am ure with

cloth for their uniforms. Thus, both the producers and the state preferred to use this

intermediary institution. The survival pattern, as put forward by Faroqhi, constitutes a

counter-argument for the view which involved an evaluation of the guilds as symbols

of backwardness.^*^ The other type of evolution by the guilds was characterized by a

limit on the guilds' sphere of activity. This type of limit was premised on the practice

of gedik diad was a consequence of the principle of "provisionalism" . ’’

These approaches may be evaluated as part of a 'universalist' historiography

that seems to have its reflections on the study of Ottoman particularism. They may be

percieved as the extentions of either some sociological approaches concerning civil

solidarity of communities and social groups within empires or as the extentions o f an

approach epitomized by the works of Susan Reynolds on European legal history,

which have an emphasis on "law based on custom" as well as an anthropological

insight.'^* In the works of İnalcık based on arcliival documents, it is not possible to

detect a society or an economy perfectly free from state regulation. As a result, it is

probably fitting to say that the above-mentioned hypotheses may be further discussed,

after the examination of particular regions' documents belonging to Ottoman lands.

Comparative studies of different localities, rather than limited surveys of overly-

^®Ibid. : 93.

■’^Engin Akarh (1985-86), "Gedik ; Implements, Masterships, Shop Usufruct and Monopoly Among Istanbul Artisans, 1750-1850," WissenschaftskollegJahrbuch : 223-232. cited by Faroqhi (1995). 94.

^®See Susan Reynolds (1992) Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe 900-1300, St. Edmundsbury Press Ltd. Bury St. Edmunds, Suffolk.

10

Page 21: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

commercialized towns like Bursa, may shed light upon this debate on autonomy,

sultanism, or civil society'^^ in the Ottoman Empire.

One area of strict state intervention in the economy seems to preserve the

nature that was inherent during the Classical Age. Setting aside the manufacturing

sector of Ottoman economy which underwent significant changes as a result o f

political, social and economic domestic transformation that took place following the

Classical Age*“ , as well as the effects of the changing trade-routes, the price

revolution, and the capitalistic pressures that originated from the West'" the concern

for food provisioning and particularly bread production remained to be an area of state

control. During the Classical Age, the Ottoman Economy, with its regional markets

and interregional trade ways, constituted a system of provisions which could be

considered as a whole in itself.

This thesis will be limited by the subject o f bread provisioning o f the Ottoman

capital, in the eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries' setting. In this context, I

^ For a discussion of the “civil societ) ” subject of Western origins see John Hall (1995). “In Search of Civil Societv'.’' Ed. Civil Society, Theory, History, Comparison, Polity Press, UK: 1-31

■’'Tialil İnalcık (1980), "Military and Fiscal Transfomiation of the Ottoman Empire. 1600-1700," AO, VI: 283-337.“"The storv of the development of Western capitalism and the position of the Ottoman State and the Ottoman Economy within this picture has been a subject of a whole set of literature. Ottoman Economy has been previously analyzed using the theories of ‘The Asiatic Mode of Production’; Weberian Modernization Perspective’. These theories have been criticized to be ‘a-historical views in which ‘East ’ is defined as a world where any progress is virtually impossible, where the economy is stagnant, where ‘despotic rulers’ have no reasons to legitimize themselves as opposed to the atomic society which cannot realize the formation of private property and the class struggles that went together. These approaches were used as ‘justifications’ for Western interference in the East, particularly the Imperial expansion of the West in non-Western areas. ( For the critiques and the theoretical discussion,see: Huri İslamoğlu-İnan (1991) Osmanli İmparatorluğunda Devlet ve Köylü(State and Peasantry İn the Ottoman Empire-Translated by SabriTekay) İletişim Yayınlan, İstanbul. ) On the other hand, within the Wallerstenian 'World System Perspective' the history of the peripherialization of the Ottoman Empire has been considered, which has also been subject to criticism for being a merely economic' approach.

‘'“Femand Braudel (1979) Civilization and Capitalism l5th-lHth Century, The perspective o f the World, (Trans. S. Reynolds)Harper & Row, Publishers, New York: 467-484. See also André Raymond

Page 22: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

propose that there was a pragmatic sphere of state-decisions while interfering in the

economy. Accordingly, in the first part of the study, wheat and flour supplies, where

the grain came from; ports o f entry into the Ottoman market, and the agents of

distribution of flour, in other words state control over the distribution o f flour will be

handled. Some primary sources that will be analyzed in this chapter are documents o f

the Muhimme Defterleri o f Başbakanlık Ottoman Archives belonging to the Classical

Age which will be scrutinized in order to construct a picture of and with what types o f

tools and motivation the Ottoman State intervened in grain production during the

Classical Age when the empire had reached its bounds as the 'World Economy' of the

Middle East, in Braudelian terms. Secondly Cevdet Belediyye documents of the

eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries will be scrutinized . Some documents of kadi

court records will be used to explain the method of flour storage. The eighteenth

century constituted a period where some pec-uliarities can be singled out in relation to

the bread provisioning question. One is concerning giain trade. This is the challenge

the Ottoman State (and the Istanbul market in particular) faced as European demand

for Middle Eastern grain began to offer significantly higher prices for the Levant grain

than the Ottoman government This increased inclination toward contraband grain

trade and created the need to put forward extra efforts o f control, on the part of the

Ottoman State. Another point is the increased population of the capital via migration

by the eighteenth century, which was an additional challenge for the state.“*' A third

characteristic of this period is the transformation of the unkapani (the flour market)

(1995) Osmanli Döneminde Arap Kentleri(Grandes villes arabes a I ’epoque ottomane,(1985) Trans. All BerktayJTanh Vakfi Yurt Ya>inlan, Istanbul.

this context, see Appendix I. a report bv- Tatarcık Abdullah Efendi, TOEM, no:44,Published by Osman Nuri Ergin (1922) Mecelle-i I'mur-i Belediyye, Istanbul: 774-75.

12

Page 23: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

into a more commercialized exchange market. In this framework, it is possible to point

at mediator-officers who served in the kapan.

In the following chapter, bread poducers will be considered. The subject will

be analyzed with emphasis on the development o f gedik which was the license of

production and sale of a commodity or the distribution o f a monopoly right by the

government. Bread production will be handled as a sphere o f monopoly that survived

even after the abolishing of monopolies by the 1838 Anglo-Ottoman Commercial

Treaty. The documents used in this analysis are publishings of Osman Nuri in his

Mecelle, and some records out of kadi court records o f the towns of Bursa and

Ankara.

The last chapter will be focused on the institution of ihtisab or market policing.

For this part, a nineteenth century kadi court record document belonging to the town

of Ankara will be analyzed. In this context, bread policing, in other words, the control

over the quality and the price of bread will be emphasized ihtisab will be considered

as an institution of the classical age that managed to survive until the mids of the

nineteenth century.

13

Page 24: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

CHAPTER I

THE QUESTION OF PROVISIONING

1.1 State Policy

Provisioning of a crowded city with the crucial foodstuff: "bread" constituted a

multi-dimentional challenge for the pre-capitalist, early modern state. In the case of

Istanbul and the Ottoman state, the mechanism of coping with this challenge has been

viewed within three main sections. The most extensive study on this subject has been

made by Rhoads Murphey.' In this context, Murphey has pointed at the first step to be

the cultivation and harvesting of grain; the next step as the transportation and storage

of grain at the center, or the capital; and the last point as the allocation and the final

distribution to consumers. This last function has been further divided into groups as

milling and refining, weighing and inventory, determination o f government price

support levels, establishment of distribution priorities, elaboration and policy of

market control mechanisms. Bread had a similarly important role in the provisioning o f

powerful states. For example, during the eighteenth century, British governments were

for the most part measuring state-administered, state-subsidized, taxed economic

entities concerning grains, flour and bread. Looking at the way Ottomans dealt with

this question throughout the centuries, it becomes evident that state never fell short of

'At this point it is appropriate to remind the work of Lütfi Güger, and that of E\angelia Balta which is particularly focused on the rural production in the network of bread production, and the price- determination mechanism in the region of Salónica.

“Christian Petersen ( 1995). Bread and the British Economy c .1770-1870, ed. Andrew Jenkins. Scolar Press, England.

lA

Page 25: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

a strict motivation for economic regulation.^ In other words, the Ottoman state did not

incline towards a liberal policy when "bread o f the masses" was concerned. In this

respect, government policies were consistent with and parallell to the practices o f the

Classical Age.

By the time eighteenth century was reached, the two treaties namely

Passarowitz (1718) and Küçük Kaynarca (1774); moreover the Russian occupation o f

Crimea constituted a turning point for the balances of grain trade. These treaties

implied the 'isolation' of the Ottoman lands from larger borders, economically. At the

same time, eighteenth century was a period of growth in population.^ As the state's

control over Danubian provinces loosened, and as the population grov^h reached high

levels, food provisioning became more difficult. This was a time when the government

adopted an "inward looking" provisioning policy turned towards internal trade.® Grain

of Istanbul came from three essential sources: the Danubian area, Mediterranean

coasts. Black Sea region, and Egypt. Grain transportation was directed towards three

main destinations: First, towards Istanbul and other metropolitan centers. Secondly,

towards import-dependant desert regions such as Hicaz, and thirdly, towards the

army, wherever it was.’ For instance, in 1047-1049 (1637-39) when the army had

gone to the Bagdad campaign, on the way to and from Bagdad, (from Üsküdar, İzmit,

Eskişehir, Akşehir, Konya, Adana, Aleppo, Diyarbakır, Musul, to Bagdad and from

^Rhoads Murphey (1988) “Pro\ isioning Istanbul: The State and Subsistence in the Early Modem Middle East,” Fooi/ani/Fboi/wavs, Vol: 2; 221.

''İnalcık (1980).

^See the report of Tatarcık Abdullah Efendi as the Appendix; I

®R. Murphey (1988): 220.

■Ibid: 221.

Page 26: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Musul, Diyarbakır, Malatya, Tokat, Amasya, Tosya, Bolu, İzmit, to Üsküdar) the total

amount of grain consumed by the army reached as much as 1.559.917 kites o f barley,

1.886.751 loaves of bread, and 43.924 kites of flour.* In 1183 (1769), due to the

Russian campaign. Black Sea wheat was entirely reserved for the army and Istanbul

received all o f Mediterranean wheat.

Since locally, provisioning had priority, illegal grain export was punishable by

death. On the other hand, internal grain trade was allowed with official permission.

"Shortage", if not "famine" determined the destination of the grain. When shortage

took place in certain areas of the empire, internal trade was motivated to make up for

these losses. It seems that more prosperous areas provided for the shortage. In case a

general crop failure or famine took place, the government would offer “partial rebates

or full tax waivers” ." A government record of the classical age dated 24 Cumade'l

ahire 994 (12 June 1586)" shows that upon shortage o f wheat in Rhodes, the dizdars

o f Sultaniye and Kilidülbahr were ordered to send 200 mudds o f grain to the island.

However, since shortage appeared in Istanbul, as well, the destination was changed

towards the capital. This order was to rearrange the journey to Rhodes once more,

since the shortage in Rhodes turned out to be severe.

*Liitfi Güçer (1964). ATI-M 71 Asırda Osmanli Înıparatolıığunga Hububat Meselesi ve Hububattan Alınan Vergiler, İÜİF Yay. Semıet Matbaası, İstanbul: 138.

®CB No: 393.

'°L. Güçer( 1951-52), IFM, 13: 79-89 cited by E. Balta (1994) ‘T he Bread in Greek Lands During the OHomatiKvAQ,” AÜDTCF Tarih Araştırmaları Dergisi, XVI, 27: 202.

" Murphey (1988): 218.

’-MD Vol: 61: 9-4.

16

Page 27: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

1.2 Grain Transport by the Government: Dealing With Contraband Trade

During the eighteenth century, the primary challenge to internal trade was the

European demand for grain motivated by the devaluation of the currency, as well as an

increased demand for wheat on a worldwide scale, after 1748.*^ On the other hand,

shipping and transportation of grain had one outstanding limit: time. The perfect

timing had to be attained to avoid spoilage or wastes of grain in stormy seas. This was

a universal problem. A cargo of damp wheat which was "to prone to heat or rot" had

to be consumed quickly, or transported before damage occured. One had to be

especially careful when sending flour because of its propensity to stale, particularly in

summer. In summer, rivers could dry out, or in winter, they could flood or freeze.*“*

Therefore, between the harvest and the winterstorms, a careful time-management was

necessary to transport grain.*’ This would only be attained by the construction and

efficient allocation of a state-owned transportation fleet The state activity in this

sphere included prevention of contraband trade; building and maintaining grain

transport vessels; employing boats (rencber gemisi) to supplement the fleet, arranging

the right arrival time and determining price arbitration and a fair freight

charge. *^Prevention of contraband trade is a well documented aspect o f this structure.

The measures included export bans on grain, double-weighing of cargoes both at the

port of departure and at the port of destination, and confiscation of cargoes of ships

'^Balta(1994): 217.

'“'Christian Petersen (1995): 152.

'^Murphey(1988): 221.

'%id: 222.

17

Page 28: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

caught at wrong routes,’’ Some documents belonging to the Classical Age, display the

emphasis placed on grain transportation as follows:

"In Gurre RA 1001 (1592), kadi of Rodoscuk had been ordered:

Previously, an imperial order had been sent, which put a ban on bringing wheat to the

ports of Ebrice, Karaincir, Ereğlü, Mağazirönü and Karagözönü where wheat was

illegally sold to Europeans. The valid market price of wheat in that area was 20 akça

per kile. At the same time, some vessel-owners, Memi Reis and a non-Muslim reis

bought the wheat and sold it to Europeans at 60-70 akça per kile in İpsala, Keşan,

Inez, Kavak, Malkara and Hayrebolu, Moreover, their vessels were full of guns and

fireballs therefore it was difficult to capture these people. In this framework, special

attention was necessary concerning requisition of wheat at the above-mentioned towns

and ports. Selling wheat to other places than Istanbul was prohibited."

"In 6 Muharram 1001 (1592), kadis of Karaçirmen. Balçık, Akkirman, Kili

and ibrail coasts had been ordered:

The price of wheat in the above-mentioned regions has been raised, *Local

price of bread in those regions has been altered Consequently, the merchants who buy

wheat from the Black Sea region have begun to sell it at higher prices, in Istanbul.

This has led to shortage of wheat and therefore, the above-mentioned Black Sea

' 'Murphey (1988): 222.

zahire babında ziyâde ihtimam idüb İstanbul’dan gayri yerlere zahire verdinneyüb emr-i şerifime muhalif 'amel idenleri isim ve resimleriyle yazub sudde-i saadetime yazub 'arz eyleyesin ki haklarından geline.Various factors could effect the price of bread such as local demand and supply, the cost o f transport, and the degree of market regulation. For further discussion and comparison with the British grain market, see Petersen (1995): 164.

1-8

Page 29: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

towns must re-organize bread making by producing 1,5 vukiyye o f bread at 1 akça.

Wheat must be bought accordingly and illegal storage o f wheat must be prevented" ,

"In 5 Cumade’l-ahire 1000 (1592), kadis of Mediterannean shores had been

ordered to control the vessels that carry grain from these shores to Istanbul. This

procedure has various steps: To prevent the delay o f departure of these ships towards

Istanbul. To record the amount of wheat each vessel’s reis (captain o f a merchant

vessel) takes. To send this defter record with the vessels, under the supervision o f

trustworthy men chosen among hisareris and others so that upon their arrival in

Istanbul, this recorded amoum can be demanded from the ship owner. To demand

imperial order from the vessel-owners who arrive to take wheat". The emphasis on the

strict control of the sale and shipment of Istanbul’s wheat is apparent in the phrase:

Istanbul zahiresi sa’ir umtira kiyas olunmaz tedariki beğayet mühimdir.

Her birinüz evkat basiret üzere olub ikdam ve ihtimamla dakika fevt

eylemeyesiz.

In 13 ZA 1001 (1592), The sancakbegs and kadıs at the Black Sea shores had

been ordered to inform the capital about the kile price of all grains including wheat,

barley, corn, etc. at the Black Sea; and about the reason of the difference in weight

between Black Sea kile and Istanbul kile.^'

"In 6 Muharrem 1001 (1592)^^, kadis of the Meditteranean coasts had been

ordered:

'%ID, Vol:69, 523-362.

MD, Vol: 69, 467-235.

MD, Vol: 69, 3-2.

” MD, Vol: 69, 516-359

19

Page 30: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

This is a time of wheat shortage in Istanbul. Therefore, the Meditteranean

wheat’s arrival is to be guaranteed by an official who has been sent to the said region,

to watch over the shipment process as well as the journey to Istanbul."

Derğâh-ı mu’allam çavuşlarından Yûsuf Çavuş zide kadruhu irsal

olunmuşdur.

The amount of wheat to be shipped, the name of the vessel owner and all the

details o f this process is to be recorded in a defter which is to be sent, with the wheat,

to Istanbul. The cruciality of this issue is emphasized as:

Bu huşûş sa’ir umûra kıyas olunmayub ihmal ve müşahalcden ziyade

hazer eyleyesiz.

Another point is made, which shows that European demand constitutes a

challenge to the process of wheat provision within the empire. Selling the grain to

European purchasers is to be severely punished, which is made clear in this imperial

order as:

k iiffa i“! hakisare virillm esi m em nii'u hümayunumda ecdadım ruhiyçünbir vochilc hakUırumızdan gcIinUı ki sa’irlerc rtuıcib-i ibret olıırsu/ dahi

ana göre mukayyed olasız.

At later dates, as mentioned earlier, during the eighteenth century, the

provisioning question was more difficult to solve due to persistent wars. Still, main

ports of wheat transport were those of the Danube, Black Sea and Egypt. In 1186

(1772), an imperial order ‘V as released to transport and purchase 2200 keyls o f

İstanbul! wheat from Sultan Yeri- Dağ Ardı kazası, to the capital:

İşbu bin yüz seksen altı senesine mahsub asitâne-i sa’âdetde ‘ibadu’İlahın

rOz-merreleriyçün Sultan Yeri ve nam-ı diğer Dağ Ardı kazasından iki

bin iki yüz keyl-i İstanbul! hınta...

’^CBNo: 5219.

kevl of İstanbul differed in acight from a keyl of another region in the empire.

20

Page 31: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

The wheat was to be brought to the dock o f Karaağaç where an officer called

Mehmed Ağa was to take the wheat over

Karaağaç İskelesine naki ve tesyır ve ta'yln olunan Mehmed Ağa’ya

teslim.

Mehmed Ağa, who was apparently the requisition agent, would purchase the

wheat over 60 akças per keyl of Istanbul

ve lâzım gelen bahâlarıyla ağa-yı merkum yedinden ‘an nakd sağ akça

olmak üzere beher İstanbul! kiyele altmış akça virülmek şartıyla...

In 1189 (1775), in order to prevent hindrances to incoming grain from the

Black Sea, Danubian and I'ekiur Dağı regions, a warning in the form of a ferman was

sent to the kadis, na’ibs and others concerned, at the kazâs from which wheat was

sent via the dock of Varna.

Varna İskelesine zahire naki ideğelen kazaların kuzât ve nüvvâb ve sâ’ire

hitaben sâdır olan fermân-ı ‘âllşân...

According to this, one o f the çukadârs (special sevant or missionary) o f the

Grand Vizier Halil Ağa was appointed responsible for this issue

husus-i mezbuia mübaşir ta’yin buyurulan şadr-ı â’zam çukadarlarından

Halil Ağa

This issue was first investigated from merchants and vessel owners seated at

the flour market of İstanbul.

der-i‘aliyyede mukim kapan tüccar ve hacıları ve eşhâb-ı sefâyinden

huşuş-ı mezbür istintak olundukda

As a result of this investigation, it was found out that the local grain producers

were hiding some of their wheat reserves when the official requisition agents arrived

to purchase wheat from them. Consequently, to assure the continuity of a satisfactory

amount o f grain transport to the capital, the local producers were told to manifest and

21

Page 32: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

sell real amounts o f grain reserves, after saving the amount necessary for their

subsistence.

ft maba’ad eşhâb-ı zira* at ve hıraşet haşıl eyledikleri zahirelerden

tahammül ü kot yevmiyyelerinden ziyâdesince ketm ü ihtifa eylemeyüb

bin yüz seksen dokuz senesi hasadından her kazanın sekine ve re'âyâsı

şatıluk zahiresini peyderpey iskelelere naki ve kapan tacirleri ve

yazıcıları ve kayıdcıları akçaların alub bilâtereddüd bey' ve şerait-i

mezküreyi kabul ve ta‘ahhud-ı hüccetleri ve i ‘lamları ita ve mahalline

kayd içim der-i ‘aliyyeye irsal olunması babında...

Due to an excess demand for grain at the capital in 1169 (1755)^* 25000

istanbull kiles of wheat was demanded from the İnoz (Inez) dock of the river Meriç.

Sixty akça was to be paid for every keyl of wheat.

sallar ile nehr-i İnoz’dan bahr-i asitane-i sa‘adete nakl olunmak içün

Karaatlu iskelesine nakliyyesiylc

However, in order to protect the local producers from difficulties and to

facilitate the procedure of sale, 10000 kile o f wheat was excused and 15000 kile of

wheat was immediately demanded,

lakin, hem fukara-yi ahaliye veslle-i husul-i şuhulet ve hem mübaya'anın

serl'an tahşlline sebeb ü ‘illet olmak içün mâ‘dası bilatavakkuf edaya

müsâra'at ve bir hissesi ğirüye kaçmamak vechiyle tekmllen teslime

cümlesi dâmen dermeyan gayret eylemeleri şartıyla heman on bifi kilesi

‘afv ve hatt-ı tenzil ve ma‘da onbeşbiö kilesi mu'accelen tahşll olunmak

üzere...

The alternative regions which provided the grain of Istanbul were Egypt and

the Black Sea region (Akkirman). In 1237 (1821)^’ three cargoes of Egyptian wheat

25,CB No: 5236.

22

Page 33: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

were sent to Istanbul from the dock of Iskenderiyye. In the documtent, cooperation o f

the governor o f Egypt, Mehmet Ali Paşa is mentioned,

iskenderiyye İskelesinden Mısır Valisi devletlü Mehmed ‘Ali Paşa

Hazretlerinin inzimam-ı dâyi’-i hamiyyetleriyle

First 14257.5, then 1244, and finally 8051 keyis of wheat was transported to

İstanbul and placed in the storehouse at the Imperial Maritime Arsenal. Wheat was

taken to İstanbul by British vessels owned by an English merchant as recorded in

memos released by the "emin" of the Maritime Arsenal.

bu def’a İnğilterelü (... ) bazirğanın süvarisi Corci kapudân, sefinesiyle

ondöribin ikiyüz elliyedi buçuk keyl ve yine bâzirğan-ı mesfurun

süvarisi ( ...) kapudân sefinesiyle sekiz bin elli bir keyl ki cem‘an

otuzikibin beşyüzelli buçuk keyl hınta vârid ve anbar-ı ‘âmireye teslim

olunmuş olduğunu anbâr emini efendi bendelerinin merbütan takdim-i

savb-ı sâmileri kılınan üçkıt‘a memhür ‘ilm ü haberlerinden müstabân

olmağla...

The payment in return for this wheat was made b> the zahire hâzinesi (grain

treasury) of the empire,

icab iden bahası ba‘de’l-hesab zahire hâzinesinden virülmek üzere

ka’imesinin i’tâsı huşuşunda emr ü ferman hazret-i menlehüT-emrindir.

As mentioned earlier, the main source of wheat for Istanbul was the Danubian

region. We have already seen an example of a document for the provisioning of

İstanbul by Egyptian wheat. In fact, Egypt served efficiently in times of crop failures in

the Danubian Area. As a result o f drought that took place in the Danubian area, in

1209 (1791), Egyptian wheat was demanded by the capital. 28

26,CB No: 5035.

-■'CB No: 4567. -®CB No: 548.

23

Page 34: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Bu sene-i mübarekede âsitane-i ‘aliyyenin kileri müşayesinde olan beher

Tuna ve Bahr-i siyah sevahili iskelelerine merbut kazalarda zeha’irin

kılleti bedidar...

... Tekfur Dağı ve Karaağaç ve Siroz ve Yenişehir ve Selanik ve Eğriboz

havalisinde kuraklık aşikar ve bu cihetden tersane-i ‘amirede vakT miri

zahire anbarlarının zikr olunan mahallerden beher sene m ü‘tad olan

tertibatına halel ve noksan terettüb idüb...

..beher sene anbar-ı ‘amireye cem‘ ü iddihar olunan zahire tertibatının

noksanlar tekmiliyçün Şayda ve Yafa iskelelerinden ve sa’ir havali-i

‘Arabistandan külliyetlü zahire tertib ve hazine ile mübaya'acı ve

mübaşirler ta‘yin olunmağla canib-i Mısır’dan dahi ikiyüzbin kile hınta

tertib ve şeyh’ül-belde İbrahim Beğ ve M irü’l-hac Sabık Murad Beğ

kullarına hitaben balası mübarek hatt-ı humayun-ı şevketmakrun ile

müveşşah ferman-ı ‘alişan tasdir ve ol tarafa tesyir olunmuş idi...

Looking at similar records falling in the time interval of 1150/ 1250 (1740-

1840), it may be possible to roughly determine the main ports, centers of grain

transport to Istanbul (and sometimes to the army) and the way of transport used in

these operations. Such records indicate that wheat (or grain) was transported from:

Ağriboz by vessels (1204/1789)^^, Kostendil and Salónica via the sea (1183/1769);

Egypt (1217/1802), Priştina (especially for the army in 1128/1716), the Meriç area by

rafts via the rivers on the Meriç-İnoz (Inez) way (1169/1755), Moldavia (1168/1755);

Rusçuk (1152/1739); the Black Sea by vessels (1198/1784); Bulgaria (1203/1789),

Golos (1186/1772); Selonica ( 1163/1750); Meditteraean -Rumelian shores

■ CB Numbers are, consequently: 444; 3527; 4181; 4738; 1800; 1726; 6182; 5724; 5725; 4365; 4403; 4443; 4492; 4033; 2676; 2691; 2888; 2928, 272; 111; 181; 192; 289; 305; 402; 417 .

lU

Page 35: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

(1204/1789); Suğla (1202/1788); Crimea by sea (1176/ 1763); Bergos and Alçaklar (a

series o f ports of the Danube) (1190/1776); Çekmece (2303/1789); Sofia

(1183/1769); Kocaeli (1184/1770), İbrail (1215/1800); Sayda (1195/1781); Akkirman

(1173/1759); Kastamonu (1239/1823) ; Syria (1209/1794); Siroz (1156/1744);

Köstence (1173/1759), Lazkiye and Aleppo (1225/1810); Silivri (1209/1794); İzmit

(1236/1821).

1.3 Storage

Storage was a significant aspect of provisioning. As division of labor between

towns and the country appeared, and "as metropolitan vulnerability increased" in

England, one proposal for solving the problem of grain, was building public

metropolitan granaries, as before the Great Fire of London This measure was to

facilitate the continuity of supplies by storing up surplus of glut and then releasing it in

times of dearth, thus meeting need and checking speculation. '” In İst inbul, large and

long-term storage bins were built by the state to meet the crowded city’s grain

requirement for several months, The dimentions of the grain provision project

required state supervision by officials- to buy grain at harvest time, to transport it, to

store it and to distribute it to consumers at suitable price ceilings (narh).

^T*etersen (1995): 156.

'Ibid: 231.

Murphey(1988): 228,

25

Page 36: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Istanbul’s daily grain requirement: 33

Date Estimate of Population Daily grain Reseñ e grain storage

consumption capability

1717 310,000 8,000 kiles (205.25 300,000 kiles=

tons) 37 days’ supply

1757 330,000 497 tons 400,000 kiles=

21 days' supply

1828 360,000 40,000 kiles ?

(1,026 tons)

It seems that physically, wheat was best kept in underground storerooms. M iri

(state-owned) wheat was stored in large quantities for the purpose o f provisioning,

Anbars (storehouses) which provided bakers with flour, in Istanbul were Tersane,

Üsküdar, Öküzlimaru, İsakçı Anbarlan.^·* These store houses contained flour from

various localities and the flour would be distributed not only to official bakeries, but

also to other establishments, For instance Laleli İmareti received its wheat from the

Tersane storehouse for the production of fod la (a loaf of bread formerly distributed in

the soup kitchens). The major function of storing wheat and flour was to keep a

stable level of provision for the bakeries o f the capital. The continuity o f incoming

wheat from different sources depended on certain conditions. As mentioned

previously, transportation was premised on both a peaceful environment as much as

^ “In Paris, the daily bread consumption was 600 grams of bread per head” in 1880. Maguelonne Toussaint-Samat (1987/1992), A History o f Food, Trans. From French b>' Anthea Bell, Blackwell Reference: 239.

CB, No: 4103, Date: 1180 (1766)

CB. No: 1028, Date: 1206 (1792)

26

Page 37: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

suitable weather conditions. Transportation of wheat or flour was for the most part

carried out by boats via the sea or via the rivers, "Before the rail age, bread stuffs

moved cheply on water, dearly on land" In any case, winter brought about

difficulties o f transportation by boat. In times of irregular transportation, official

storehouses would guarantee continuous wheat distribution. 40,000 kiles^^ of wheat

was distributed to the bakers o f Istanbul in 1183 from the Bahriyye storehouse

3 8because of bad weather.

In the provinces, privately owned wheat was stored in smaller underground

wells called kuyu. An example for this storage method has been reported in a court

case of the seventeenth century Ankara. The record concerns theft o f wheat out of

kuyu reported to the kadi including a description o f the theft which reveals the

storage method of wheat in wells;

mezbûr Hüseyin bizim kuyulanimz açub hayli buğdaylarımız sirkat

eylemiş bi hasbi’ş-şer'" mûcibin taleb iderüz didüklerinde mezbûr dahi

min-el-vaki Pervane nam bir köle ile varub mezbûrlarm kuyuların açub

mezbûr Pervane kuyulariñ içine ğirüb çuvala koyub baña kaldırub ben

çekdüm deyu cevab virüb b i’t-taleb kayd olundu. (11 C 1001/1592)^^

Storage was a state funded project. The centralized planning of grain transport

and distribution was improved with the establishment o f the zabire nezâreti in 1213

^^Petersen (1995): 150,

Weights and measurements differed among different localities. According to Halil İnalcık’s work on Ottoman metrologv’, one kile of Istanbul was equal to 37cm^ Wheat would be commonly measured in kile (keyl or keylçe), mudd and vukiyye . One vukiyye (okka, ûkiye) was equal to 400 dirhems. ( Ottoman Metrolog>·.· 340)

CB, No: 2715, Date: 1183

39 ACR,IV/451.

27

Page 38: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

(1799). This was a sub-ministry endowed with a budget with 5000 kise (2.5 million

guruş) from the treasury 40

1.4 Unkapam

As Halil İnalcık has illustrated, " for each major item o f necessisies, like wheat,

butter, honey, cloth silk and leather, a special market or hall was Unkapani

or kapan-i dakik (the flour market) was functioning to meet the wholesale flour

requirements of the city’s bakers as well as the center where wheat and flour were

weighed and taxes such as kantariye were ch a rg ed .Is ta n b u l unkapam was located

at the entrance of Haliç (the Golden Horn). Within the flour market, there were 400

shops of flour merchants, according to Evliya Çelebi.·* Bakers were obliged, by law,

to have a minimum of two to six months o f flour stocks at depots (anbar).“’“’ This

requirement of the bakers, the obligations the merchants and ship owners and any

disputes among these agents were examined by the officials present at the unkapam.

These officials were mainly, the nizain usías (inspectors the requirements o f bakers),

the kapaa hac/s (merchants of wheat and grain), and the kapan n a ’ib i (the surrogate

judge seated at the flour market, who watched over disputes, kept a defter in order to

inspect stock requirements). Other persons related with the kapan were miibaya''acts

(the requisition agents), and the rii ’esa of the vessels (vessel captains responsible to

carry the necessary amount of wheat at the right time). The responsibility shared

Murphey (1988): 231.

'"İnalcık (1970): 217.

‘'“İnalcık (1980). 1.

Evliya Çelebi(1314/1896) Seyahatname, İstanbul I: 350, cited by Murphey(1988): 229.

''' Ibid.

28

Page 39: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

among these agents and officials may be handled in two primary divisions. One

consists overseas transport and the timely arrival of the grain, while the other concerns

proper distribution of grain to the bakers, regarding their regulations and baking

requirements. The relationship among these agents has been well documented.

According to an Istanbul court record dated 21 cemaziye’l-ahar 1200 (1786)“* ,

In the past and since, in the flour market, the relationship between the ship owners

(merchants) and the bakers has been regulated by the kapan n â ’ib i efendi (the judge

of the flour market). The center o f this regulatory mechanism is the place called

çardak ox çahârdâkoî the unkapani. In order to enable the regulation function o f this

office, both the bakers and the merchants have had their trustworthy representatives at

the çardak. The kethüda of the bakers, as well as six selected members o f the kapan

merchants constitute this special group. These six merchants share the function of

inspecting the kapan and each week three among them are present at the çardak, by

the sultanic order. These six merchants, together with the kethüda of the bread-

makers, have been ordered to find out reasons behind delays o f distribution after the

arrival of wheat vessels at the kapan. And once more, the timely distribution o f wheat

at the kapan and the priority of this issue among any other is emphasized:

imdi zahire huşûsu akdem-i umûr-ı lazımüT-ihtimâlden olduğuna

binâ’en gelen zehairin bila-te’hır tevzf ve taksimi esbabının istihsaline

d il^at lâ-büd olmağla...

İCR No: 65; Osman Nuri Ergin, Mecelle, I: 790-791.

29

Page 40: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

1.5 Conclusion

Provisions of the Ottoman empire's crowded towns and cities with the basic

necessities, primarily with bread was the problem of utmost importance and

precedence. Istanbul as the heart of the empire had the lion's share in cruciality.

Istanbul's grain came from three main sources The essential wheat depot was the

Danubian region, from which grain was transported both via the sea as well as by raft.

Western Anatolia-the Mediterranean lands stood out as an equally significant supply

center with its high quality grain production. Black Sea, or the hinterland of the ports

of Kilia and Akkerman was the next important grain supplier. As an additional region

o f incoming wheat, Egypt constituted a substitute reserve for grain.

Provisioning was a state-led project. State control was inherent beginning from

the cultivation of grain up to its harvesting, milling, refining, requisition,

transportation, distribution, baking and sales to the population. During the eighteenth

century, the Ottoman state was facing various challenges concerning this project. In

the first place, state had lost its control over the Danubian lands. Secondly, population

of Istanbul had reached excessive numbers over 300000. Moreover, demand for grain

had increased in Europe and as the Ottoman currency was devaluated, Europeans

were willing to offer higher prices for grain, compared to prices offered by the

Ottoman government, which was encouraging contraband trade.

State responded to the challenges in the form of measures and checks. These

measures included seed distribution to the peasants in order to guarantee the

continuity of production; double-weighing of cargoes at the time of departure and at

the time of arrival at the destination; having large miri store houses and minimum

stock requirements to prevent dearth; having centralized control over incoming grain

30

Page 41: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

and its distribution at the unkapani; employing official requisition agents, heads o f

bakers, and a judge at the flour market to inspect the normal flow o f grain provisions

for the capital. In 1799, a special ministry was established for the provisioning

requirement. The ministry had a separate share o f the state treasury. Provisioning thus

had a complex structure and the state undertook the project o f a time management in

order to provide the needed amounts of grain at reasonable prices, and to prevent

losses o f grain due to delays in transportation.

31

Page 42: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Leí the number o f bakers be always complete, and the place where they work

always kept neat and clean.

—Charlemagne^

CHAPTER II

MONOPOLY RIGHTS OF BREAD PRODUCERS IN THE OTTOMAN EMPIRE

2.1 The Ğedik Practice

The concept of ğedik is central to understanding the organisation of Istanbul

artisans during the second part of the eighteenth century and the beginning of the

nineteenth It stands out as a significant practice with the political and legal

connotations brought with it. The literary meaning of ğedik is a "slot" or a "breach".

Gedikli on the other hand, has a meaning of "seniority" or "tenure" in profession. The

term "ğedik" has been noted to have meant the tools and equipment in a shop

necessary to practice a particular trade. By the nineteenth centuiy, however, it is likely

that it came to mean the right to practice a particular trade at a specific place equipped

with the necessary tools and means. The third meaning acquired by the word ğedik

was the special legal document entitling the holder to "full usufruct over a work

premise".

By the eighteenth century, most of the Ottoman craftsmen were in difficulty.

As mentioned earlier, it is possible to view artisanal activities in three major categories:

production of manufactured goods, production of foodstuffs and production o f

services. If we consider manufacturers' situation during the late eighteenth and

nineteenth centuries, it appears that cheap and standard European imports were

32

Page 43: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

constituting a challenge to the local production. As to the position o f food makers or

artisans of services, persistent wars affected them directly, since they had to provide

the army with orducu." Moreover, craftsmen had to provide their members who went

to war, with the capital they needed. As a result, a competitive environment was

formed where "getting away from" the service o f orducu or the payments related to

this service, was targeted. Avoiding the obligation was only possible through staying

out of record.·^ Consequently, guilds and their masters, who were trying to preserve

their traditional organisation, were motivated towards a new measure. The above-

mentioned pressures on the artisans created the tendency to form the institution of

gedik.·’ This process began with the act of Istanbul artisans who started to register

their tools and equipment with their kethüdas. They began to call these tools "gedik",

their owner "gedikli", and the registration document - "gedik paper".^ The person who

was to become a master, acquired a "slot" from another master along with the "gedik"

paper.

Uşül-ı inhisarın bedayeti olan takriben 1140 tarihinde esnafın ‘adedi

ustalık namıyla tahdid olunmuş ise de sonraları gedik namını almı- ve

gedik ta’birinden âlât-i şanaiye murad olunmuştur...’

'M. Toussaint (1987/1992): 233.•Craftsmen were obliged to accompany the army in order to provide the army with tools, equipment, food and with senices as such. This seivicc was called “orducu çıkarmak”.

^The Ottoman terminology for being recorded is ’ sebt-i defter” and staying out of record is “haric’ez- defter”

"Suraiya Faroqhi. (1995) “Ottoman Guilds in the Late Eighteenth CenUiry: The Bursa Case,” Making a Living in the Ottoman Lands 1480 to ¡820, The Isis Press, Istanbul: 98.

^"Bir kimse çırak ve kalfahkdan yetişüb de ınünhall olan veya lüzüm-ı şahlh üzerine müceddeden acılan bir ustalık makâmma geçmedikçe ya'ni gedik sahibi olmadıkça dükkan açarak icra-yı san'at e ticaret idemez idi zira ba‘zı imtiyaz ve şerâ’iti hâvi eşnâf yedlerinde fermanlar ve beratlar var

idi." Sidki(1325) Gedikler, Dersaadet: 15.

*E. D. Akarlı, “Gedik,” {l9S5-İ6)WissenschaftskoIlegJahrbııch 19: 225-231.

'Sidki (1325).

33

Page 44: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

In some cases, a new work establishment was built for him with the permission

of other masters. This complexity in the use o f gedik has naturally led to certain

difficulties in both implementation and comprehension of the related practices. A

conflict often emerged from the fact that gedik also constituted a security against

credit. When an artisan could not pay his debts, his assets would be sold to pay these

debts, to the highest bidder. These highest bidders could just as well be outsiders to the

guild. The artisans were complaining about such developments and the involvement of

"clumsy handed outsiders"* in their trade. They demanded the increased control of

gedikli masters over the transfer and the use o f gedik as credit, or security.

Another problematic aspect of gedik was concerned with the property relations

during this period. This involved the claim of the artisan, on the use o f a workplace, on

account of his ownership of the implements kept in it. Most buildings in Istanbul were

owned by waqfs. According to Islamic Law, waqf property was inalienable and could

only be rented for short terms. Only in case of a dilapidated property, could the

tenants help ameliorate the waqf revenues. This would only be possible through special

arrangements of either the mükâfata (inuqaia‘ali) contract, or the icareteyn {ijaratayn)

contracts.

Mukata‘a implied that the tenant received coproprietorship or permanent lease

in return for a downpayment, such as an immovable like trees. He could bequeath his

rights to his legitimate heirs and he could transfer his usufhict to third parties. The

icareteyn contract, served as means to restore and put into use müsakkafât (destroyed

fields or immovables) and gave more limited rights to the tenant. In this case, the

tenant enjoyed a perpetual lease over the waqf property. He could transfer usufruct

® “ham-desf ’ in Ottoman.

3A

Page 45: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

only with the permission of the trustees. He could only bequeath to his immediate

children. If he had no children, his rights would go back to the waqf There seem to be

two major reasons for the appearance of the icareteyn system. One is the loss o f waqf

property through some disasters such as fire or earthquake. The other is the

deprivation of fixed waqf revenues caused by inflation. As put forward by Engin

Akarli, ownership had then become a relative right that was qualified by complex

relations between different claimants to a piece o f property.“ Beginning with 1760's,

because of financial difficulties arising from warfare, the state began to borrow money

from government-controlled waqfs. At the same time, waqfs were trying to increase

their own revenues by using the above-mentioned special contracts. The increased use

of these contracts led to some conflicts between the holders of contracts and the

artisans or the shopkeepers. In such cases, artisans tried to show their gQdik-papers as

evidence of their deals with the owners, which were mostly, waqfs. Gedik papers were

recognisable by the kadis as documents of mastership and ownership o f tools, but they

were not acceptable as claims to shop space. Moreover, different crafts had different

ways of practice of their trades. Some goods were produced and sold at fixed

workshops, while some others could be sold by itinerant peddlers. This characteristic,

to<^ether with the above-mentioned claims to shop-space, led to the emergence o f two

distinct legal categories: mustakarr (mustaqarr / fixed) and hava’r (hawa’i / aerial)

gediks.

The artisan groups, thus distinguished, equipped with legal documents o f

gedik, acquired a solidarity and improved their organisation, adopting a more

®It can be said that this dual pattern gave the icareteyn contract an advantage similar to the muaccele payments concerning the iltizam practice.

10 Akarh, (1985-86): 226.

35

Page 46: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

monopolistic character. Full monopoly to the producers of a certain good was only

determined by a nizam. Selim III had only approved of the monopolies o f producers o f

basic necessities such as bread, meat, candles, etc. He had attempted to remove the

other monopolies, however, the artisans were politically strong enough to organise

uprisings until the sultan was dethroned and killed,*^

During the reign of Mahmud II, gedik was established as "the usufruct o f a

workplace equipped and reserved for the monopolistic practice of trade" In return

for this privilege, the artisans had to pay higher taxes than before. Mahmud II, by the

way, had a firm control over waqfs and he encouraged increased co-operation with the

esnaf for financial gain and political stability. In 1826, the Sultan leased the right of use

of some trade and industry in order to obtain revenues for waqfs. The gedik system

involved leasing of government's trade monopoly concerning certain commodities, or

trade practice in certain areas In order to obtain a trade licence, or gedik senedi, a

downpayment called bedel-i w u ‘acele was paid. In case of the transfer o f the gedik via

sale or inheritance, or its transfer as pledge for security, harc-i in tika l ( a transfer fee)

was paid by the gedik holders.'^ In addition to the mu'acele downpayment, a daily

amount called bedel-i m ii‘eccele was paid by the gedik holders. The government

supported esnaf in groups, to get engaged in icareteyn contracts’* via special nizams.

Gedik papers were given to places of trade, craft and commerce. Shops and

"Ibid.

'^Ibid: 227.

'^Ibid:

'''Bames (1986): 56.

’’Ibid.

'^Akarh (1985-86): 227.

36

Page 47: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

underground storerooms such as granaries, cellars and cisterns were included in this

practice,’’ The state regulated waqf-esnaf relations by assuring that gedik rights were

held by the waqfs themselves, on the condition that they would rent back to the

masters on icareteyn contracts. The contract was between the master and the waqf and

was organised according to shari‘a and sultan's nizâm, The master got perpetual lease

on gedik, and the shop itself, at a fixed rent. As mentioned before, he could bequeath it

only to his children. If none of his children became qualified masters, other masters

would lease off the gedik to a qualified person and give the income to the children. If

the master had no heirs, gedik would be auctioned from waqf hands. When the gedik

stayed with the waqf, each time it changed hands, the waqf would get a transfer fee. In

this case, the masters did not have to make a downpayment, however, they had to

donate their gediks to the w aqf’*

In sum, this type of contractual practice seems to be between the artisan and

the waqf, however, its terms were managed by the government. The government

would take into account several criteria in determining the contractual relationships

Public interest would be considered and supply of goods to the army and other aspects

of artisanship would be calculated when restricting their numbers,” Former minister of

the religious foundations, Mustafa Nuri Paşa, described the gedik practice,

distinguishing between two types of gedik. One was the restricted class; the other, the

unrestricted one. The number of the former type was fixed while the latter was given

' Bames: 57.

‘*Ibid: 229.

37

Page 48: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

to anyone who wanted to perform the trade. In other words, it was a "license or permit

to work in that craft"

In the long run, the elongated lease term of the icareteyn contract placed waqf

property in the sphere o f private ownership where it could be sold, mortgaged,

bequeathed or leased. Since the gedik practice seemed to transform evkaf property

into a type of private property which, in a way, resembled private property, it worked

against the waqfs. Waqf property was untouchable in its ideal form; neither the state

nor some other person or entity could have a claim on it. The gedik issue was subject

to change in 1838 with the Anglo-Ottoman Commercial Treaty, when all the

monopolies were abolished. In 8 Zilhicce 1277(1861) granting gediks was abolished by

a nizamname which implied that only the gediks issued prior to 1247(1831) would be

valid. Three exceptional trade groups remained to continue the gedik practice with

special government permission: the tobacconisis, flour dealers, and bakers.

Below, is an analysis o f Ottoman archival documents concerning the gedik

practice in relation to the bread producing craftsmen and their monopoly rights, which

constituted an item of special privilege, as mentioned a b o v e . T h e documents in

^°Mustafa Nuri Paşa(1328/1909) Netayic 'iil-vukiiat IV, Istanbul: 100, cited by Barnes: 57-58.It may be useful to keep in mind that practicing a craft well before the eighteenth century was

permitted and recorded by the state. Similar to the appointment procedure of a guild kethüda, craftsmen themselves were appointed with a consensus. A court record of the town of Ankara during the Classical Age displays the agreement on the appointment of bakers:Habbâz müsafir Ahmed’in ta’allı olmağm dükkânı işbu 'Abbas bin 'Abdülkerim nam kimesne 'uhdesine alub mezbûrun dahi ta’allı olmağın yerine işbu Ilüseyin bin Hızır ta’ahhüd eyleyüb mezbûrun dahi nefsine ve her haline ŞükrI bin Şa’bân kefil ve Elhac Sinân bin 'Abdullah nam kimesneler kefil oldukları kayd şodd. Hacı Mahmudun dahi ta’alll olub yerine işbu Hacı Sinan bin 'Abdullah münâsibdir deyû kethüdâ-yı şehri İbrahim Çelebi ve Şan Mustafa ve Şükrü ve flortoğlu Hacı Sinân ve Baslizâde Yusuf ve takyeci Erğâ’ib ve usta Fazlı ve şâirleri mezbûr Hacı Yusufun habbaz olunmasm taleb ideniz ve fukaraya infi'adır didiklerinde mezbûr Hacı Yusuf habbâz ta'yin olunub kayd olundu. 22 Zilhicce 1009. ACR 8/2988.

Moreo^'er. we have fetva by Ebussuud Efendi on the gedik practice. See Ahmet Akgündüz (1992).

■'Only one document analyzed is an exception in the sense that it is concerning the manufacturing sector.

38

Page 49: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

question are o f the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries since the eighteenth century

was the period of prevalence of gediks, The documents are for the most part

publications o f Osman Nuri E r g i n . To begin with, an imperial order which constitutes

an example for the continuity of the gedik practice despite the 1838 Anglo-Ottoman

Commercial Treaty will be examined.This document reveals that gediks o f the

weavers of Istanbul were allowed to exist until well after the Baltalimani Treaty.

Details o f this special permission are apparent in the document dated 8 Safer 1279 ( 24

July 1861):

The weavers of Istanbul, in the past, consisted of 91 c r a f t smen . The

production process had been limited by a fixed number of 182 workshops

(looms)- two looms for each weaver' This number was not allowed to

exceed by newcomers' participation.^^" The vacancy in case of the death of

one of the above-mentioned weavers would be filled by his son. If he did

not have one, his place would be granted to his prior journeyman

according to established rules of the past.“ The weavers had submitted

petitions at various dates in the past and had demanded the reinforcement

and continuity of these r u l e s . U p o n such requests, official orders had

been issued.

“ Osman Nuri Ergin (1922), Mecelle-i Unnir-i Belediyye, Istanbul.

‘^Divan-i Humaj-un Esnaf Defteri (1242). İnalcık Collection No: 8, Bilkent Uni\ersity Central Library.

“ mine'l-kadim doksanbir neler. DHF/D , Noi8.

^^Saltanalarinin i ’mali dahi beherinin mutasami olduğu ikişer ‘adedden yiizsekseniki ‘adod destğâhlara hasriyle. DHED, No: 8.

■^İçlerine aharinin duhulüyle mikdâr-ı mezkurun tecâ\üz itmemesi . DHED, No:8.

"’esnâf-ı merkümeden biri fevt ü halik oldukda mensiy olan dest-gâhı evlâdına; olmadığı halde eski kalfasma virülmek üzere cari olan nizâm-ı kadimlerin. DHED, No:8.

■'*nizâm-ı kadimlerin te’kld ve istikrârını şâmil tevârih-i ‘atıka-i muhtelife ile b i’l-istid’â verilen evâmir-i şerife.. DHED, No:8.

39

Page 50: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

This imperial order has been first issued in 1223, during the reign of Sultan

Mahmud II; consequently, in 1256 during the reign of Sultan Abdülmecid it was

renewed and finally, in 1279 the order was again renewed on the occasion of the

accession o f Sultan Abdülaziz to the throne. The interesting point, here, is particularly

the emr-i şerif dated 1256 which contains the explanations cited below:

With the executive improvements brought about with the Tanzimat,

monopoly rights had been prohibited by the order of the Sultan. However,

the restrictions on the number of workshops of the aforementioned

artisans were traditional regulations rather than monopoly on purchase and

sale. Therefore the renewal o f the rules were not deemed inconvenient.^^

Despite the fact that the weavers did not belong to the group of artisans who

worked for the food provisioning of the capital- whose monopoly rights were all so

naturally justifiable- they managed to maintain their gediks at the fixed number

determined in the past. This may be interpreted not only as a tneans to protect the well­

being of the artisans, but also as an attempt of the state to protect the local textile

producer from the harsh competition of European imports.

If we are to turn our attention back to the provisioning issue and the bread

question, it is possible to cite a number o f documents indicating the gedik practice.

The provisioning sphere, as discussed before, was a point of strict scrutiny and control

on the part o f the Ottoman government. Below are documents' references and official

approval o f the gedik practice, concerning the bread issue.

In 1768 for example, an official document has been issued which constitutes a

warning to reaffirm the old and established rules of the ekmekçi (bread producer) and

“ Tanziraât-1 hayriyye usül-ı mehâsin- şumülü iktizâsınca inhisar maddesi bâ hatt-ı humâyün-ı şevket-makrün memnu’ ise de esnâf-ı merküme dest-ğâhlarmıö ol mikdâra tahsisi inhisâr-ı bey’ ü şifâ kabilinden olmayub bir nevi’ nizâmları dimek olmak mülâbesesiyle tecdidinde mahzur

Page 51: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

uncu /a V/e5/(flour providers) of Istanbul. These rules found in the document dated

Evasit-i Zi'l-hicce 1181 are:

To have six months' wheat supply in the storehouses during proper periods.

To produce and sell properly baked pure, white sacred bread of the right weight, as

well as çörek (shortbread) and sim id (roll-bread) ^^over the fixed monthly price.^^Not

to close the bakeries they administered.^·* Not to neglect or delay the payments to the

state or to the merchants of the unkapani in return for the flour bought.^’ To get each

one of their names recorded in the nizâm d e f ter To have guarantors to be called

upon whenever necessary.^ In case one of them dies or moves elsewhere, and his

gedik o f uncu, çörekçi, ekmekçi or simidci is to be sold, it is their customers',

kethiidas’ and trustworthy masters' obligation to come before the kadis as guarantors.

The decision o f the court is to be sent to the vizier so that the corresponding Sultanic

order is issued. The participants get recorded in the nizam defteri and baş muhasebe

with their guarantors and only after these procedures are completed, can their gedik

olmadığından esnaf-i merkumenin istikrar-i nizâmlarını havı tecdıden 5 Cemâziyü’l-âher 1256 tarihinde emr-i şerif ışdâr ve î ’tâ olunmuş. DIIED, No:8.^°Divan-ı Humayun Buyruldu Defteri (1181/1768), Published By Osman Nuri, Mecelle:!^!.

‘(At the appropriate month or season): vakt ii zamanında altu aylık zahire der-anbar. DHBD.

‘Other wheat products may be counted as tahe kahisi; fodla; sükkeri; susamlı some of which are çörek t>pes and some deserts. See Faroqhi (1995). Osmanli Kültürü ve Gündelik Kafanı.Tarih Vakfı Yurt Yayınlan: 224-25.

■’narh-ı rûzl üzere tâmü’l-vezn hâlis ve beyaz ve tabhı nişâbmda nan-ı ‘aziz ve çörek ve simid tabh eyleyüb.. .DHBD.

‘‘mutaşamf olduklan fnmlan kapamamak. DHBD.

^^Cânib-i miriden ve kapan tüccarından aldukları zahirenin akçâsmı edada cefa ve te’hir etmemek,

^^er birinifl isra ü şöhretleriyle nizâm defterine şebt ü kayd... DHBD.

^^küfelâ ahz ve vakt-i iktizâda kefilleriyle müâhaza olunmak. DHBD.

41

Page 52: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

transfer be completed.^* And the ones who act contrary to the established rules are to

be deprived of their bakeries, mills and gediks.

The rules seem to reveal the conditions of the transfer o f a gedik. The practice

of transfer is o f particular significance for our analysis, In case o f the death o f the

gedikli master, the person to replace him is to meet the above-listed requirements. The

significance of these rules rest with certain negativities experienced in the past. In some

cases, the person who replaced the dead master turned out to be someone obscure;

someone who was lacking the necessary qualities of a master. In some cases, again,

this obscure person transferred or rented the gedik to another obscure person. As a

result, at the end, merchant's or state- property ended up debited to their accounts.

These undesirable situations resulting from the possession o f gediks by

unqualified and obscure persons, occasionally led to difficulties in the collection o f the

worth of officially distributed flour, and eventual!} to loss o f the property.“*' The

strangers who came to own gediks were people of low commercial strength. They

were not able to stock the proper amount of wheat, at the proper time. They could

continue with the trade only on a day-to-day level. As a result, in winter days, as the

^®içleründen biri şalhe-i rahm yâhud bir husUs ile diyâr-ı âhara gider oldukda mutasaiTif olduğu etmekçi ve uncu ve çörekçi ve siraidci gediğini âhara bey’e murâd eyledikde müşlerı ve kethüdaları ve ihtiyar ustalarından mO’temed kımesneler meclis-i şer’e hâzuıûn olub müşteriye yâhud yerine ikâmet etdirdiği kimesneye kethüdaları ve sâ’ir nizâm ustaları tekeffül eyleyecekleri huzOr-ı aşfiya i ’lâm olunmak ve mücebince şerefsudür iden emr-i ‘âli müşterekinin kefilleriyle n i^ m defterine ve baş muhasebeye kayd olunub... DHBD.

^Tlilâfma hareket idenlerin fnün ve değinnen \ e gedikleri âhara virülmek. DHBD.

■ "bu nizâm-ı raüstahseneye ri’âyet olumnayub içleründen biri bâlâda zikr olunduğu üzere şalh-i rahm veyâhud ahar huşuş ile diyâr-ı âhara ğitdükde yerine meçhulü’1-hâl bir kiraesneyi ikâmet, o dahi kezâlik meçhul ü ’l-hal kimesneye i ’âre yâhud icâre \e ba’zıları firâr itmekle mâl-ı miri ve mâl-ı tüccar zimmetlerinde kalub...DHBD.

■"nizâm-ı kadime ri’âyet olummyarak nizâmın ihlâlini ve huşüşen cânib-i miriden tevzi’ olunan hıntanın kıymetlerini tahsilde ‘usret ve bir vechle hasâret ve telef-i emvâl ile sâ’ir mazarratı münettic olub... DHBD.

42

Page 53: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

vessels rarely arrived at the unkabani grain was attacked by the excess demand in the

market. This led to bread scarcities and difficulties for the popula t ion ,The measures

of improvement concerning such a vital element of provision, included keeping gediks

in qualified peoples' hands.“* These measures were for the most part a repetition o f the

established rules mentioned above. Anyone who would act contrary to these rules

would be severely punished and deprived of their gediks.

The question is, how would such violations be detected before the appearance

o f bread scarcity? How would the articulation of the chains o f the process be

guaranteed before that stage'’ The responsibility rested with the judges. The issue

would be followed through the records of kapan naibi (kept by the judge at the

unkapani) tevzi’ defteri. Kapan naibi defteri would be checked each year before the

month of Nove mber .Br ea d makers who lacked the necessary amount of wheat

stocks would be deprived of their gediks.

42“ol kiraesneler ğürtih-ı milliden olmamağla şuıoıt-ı mezkur üzere \ akt ü zamanıyla zeha’ir iddihar ve cem ’ine kadirler olmayub yevmiyye ile evkât-güzar olmalarıyla eyyam-ı şitada sefa’inin kıllet-i vürüdlannda kapan-ı dakika hücum \e tazyik ve nizam-ı kadimlerine mugayir harekat-ı nabecâya tasaddi ile nan-ı ‘azizifi kılİetine ve ‘ibâdu’Il-ahın zaruretine müedda oldukları... DHBD,

■*’Uncu çörekçi, ve simidci tâ’ifesinden biri şıla-i rahm veyahud mutasarrıf olduğu fırun ve değirmenini icar veyahud gediğini bey’e murâd idenler gerek müslıın ve ğerek naşara eya-men-kane bayi’ ve müşteri ve kethüdaları ve nizam ustaları bi’l-cümle meclıs-i şer’a hâzuvın olub ... kendü cinslerinden gayra furUht ve icar ve i ’âre ittirilmeyüb kendi cinslerinden milli olub vakt ü zamanıyla zehâir iddihar ve cem’ itmek üzere tekeffül ve her hâline müteahhid olub isim ve şöhıetleriyle zabt ü tescil olunarak nizâm-ı kaviyye rabt olundukdan soma... DHBD.

‘'''tenblh ve te’kıd olunan nizama mugayir harekata cesareti zuhUr idenler Müslim ve zimmıdeh her kim ise ol makuleler şırren ve alenen tecessüsden hâli olumnayub \ e bir tarikle himaye olunmamak ve haklarında bâb-ı af mesdud olarak keyfiyyetleri sadrâzam tarafına l ’lam ile der-akab gedikleri ahara verilüb taife-i mezbUreden tard ü teb’ld olundukdan başka... DHBD.

'' Just before the arrival of the cold and the rarity of the incoming wheat. The worst thing was to leave the capital with scarcity of bread in cold winter days,

‘'^habbaz ve uncu taifesinin altı ay şitada kifayet edecek mikdâr zahireyi aldıkları ve almadıkları kaban naibi tevzi’ defterinden nümâyân olmağla Islambol kadısı olanlar bu husUsu kaban naibi defterinden dâima tecessüslerinden hali olmadıklarmdan başka, beher sene rUz-ı kasım duhûl itmezden mukaddem dahi tevzi’ defterine b i’n-nefs nazar eyleyüb altı aylık zahireleri tekmil olmayanların zahireleri tekmil itdirülmek ve muhalefet idenlerin vech-i muharrer üzre gedikleri âhara virilüb tard olunmak... DHBD.

^3

Page 54: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Following this example where the wheat stocks and transfer of gediks

constituted the central issues of discussion, we will now turn to the importance of the

gedik practice in terms of the market mechanism A record out of Istanbul kadi court

records'*’ o f the late eighteenth century (Cemaziye'l-ewel 1198/1784) is about opening

a new bakery o ï francala (fine, white bread), upon request. In the eighteenth century,

establishing new bakery would indicate creation of a new gedik i.e. a new license for

the production of bread. The document in question has been written upon a petition

submitted by some zimmi Dimitraki to the Divan-i Humayun. The place o f the bakery

in question was determined ahead There was already a bakery built on waqf land o f

Vezir Halil Hamid Paşa, in Arnavud Karyesi (present-day Arnavudköy). Bread-maker

Dimitraki demanded the permission of the sultan in order to activate this workplace,

according to the established rules of the esnaf The permission was conditioned on the

decision that would be issued by the kadt of Istanbul.

Kadi’s decision necessitated the testimony of the kethüda of the breadmakers,

Bİzâm ustas and ihtiyarlar ( elders) who have expressed the exigency of the good-

natured non-Muslim community of Istanbul, for bread.Similar to the permissions that

‘''İCR, No:51.

‘“ Francalacı esnafından Dimitraki zimmi Divân-ı hümayunuma ‘arzuhal iclüb halen şadr-ı â ’zam ve vekıl-i mutlak şadakat-ı ‘ilm düstür-ı mükenem mu’azzam müşir efham ve muhterem nizâmü’l- ’âlem vezirim Halil Hamid Paşa adamAllahute’alâ icIâlehOnun asitâne-l 'aliyyem ve mahâl-i sâ’irede hasbeten-lillah ve taliben limânzAllâhute’âla müceddeden bina ve ihyâsına muvaffık olduğı evkafına zamm ve ilhaken Boğaziçinde Amavudkaryesi nam mahalde vaki’ ‘arsa-i hâliye üzerine müceddeden bina eylediği bir bâb francalacı fırunının habbazan eşnâfımn şurüt ve nizamları üzere feth ü küşâdma kimesne tarafından müdâhale olunmamak üzere yedine emr-i şerifim l ’tâsını istid’â- yı ‘inayet eylemeğin ... hâlâ İstanbul kadısı raevlânâ Muştala zldet fezâ’iluhodan isti’lam olundukda. ICR,No:51.

■^^Âsitane-i ‘aliyyem tevâbl’inde vâki’ habbâzân eşnâfmm kethüdası ve b i’l-cümle nizâm ustaları ve tâ’ife-i mezbürenin müsinn ve ihtiyarları meclis-i şer’e ğelüb her biri takrir-i kelam ve ta’bir-i ‘anü’l-rnerâm idüb âsitane-i ‘aliyyem ve tevabl’inde kâ’in kaşabât ve kurada vaki’ ‘aliyyü’l-mizâc olub ve francala nân-ı ‘azizine muhtaç olan ‘ibadullahın def’-i müzayakaları matlüb olduğundan iktiza iden mahallerde rahmânu’l-’ibad francala fırunı küşâdma izn-i humâyunum erzân kılınmak mesbük olub... ICR, No:51.

Page 55: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

had been given to nev\ bakery establishments in Beylerbeyi and Kasımpaşa, in the past,

a new permission has been issued for the opening of new bakeries to meet the needs of

the residents o f Arnavud Karyesi. The gedik of this new bakery has been granted to

the petitioner Dimitraki.^*’

The kadi has announced that he has been permitted and licensed with a batt-i

şe r if in order to carry out his art.^^ This batt-i bumayun has been recorded by the

başmubâsebe ( head accounting office) and a fermao-i 'ahşan (sultanic order) has

been written to put it into action. ^What can be underlined in relation to the document

is that a new gedik is permitted immediately when the needs of the community are

testified by a court announcement. The testimony of trustworthy people on this issue

have constituted sufficient official proof of the need to establish a new bakery. The

decision and the issued imperial order, all depend on this testimony. The place of the

new establishment, the name of the gedik owner, and the condition that the gedik be

granted to no none else, have been followed and recorded step by step by bureaucratic

procedures.”

Similar motivation seems to be inherent in the determination o f the number o f

hassa etmekçileri ( bakers who served the palace). A record dated 18 Safer

^®Bundan akdem Beylerbeyi ve K.asımpa.şa nam mahallerde dahi küşadına izn-i humâyün-ı şevket- makrOnum erzân kılınım^ olduğundan mahrüse-i Galata’ya muzâf Beşiktaş nahiyesine tâbi’ Amavudkaryesi ve civânnda olan ‘aliyyü’l-miz.âc ‘ibâdu’l-lahın francala nan-ı ‘azizine eşedd-i ihtiyâç iİe muhtâc olduklanm ve müşarünileyhin evkâfmdan olub zikr olunan Amavudkaryesinde vâki’ Arsası üzerine bir bâb francala fınm binâ ü inşâ olunmasına izn-i humayun-ı ‘inâyetmakrunum erzân kılmub ve gediği dahi zimmi-i mesfürufi üzerine tahrir... ICR, No:51.

‘Başmuhâsebeye kayd olumnasım iltimâs ve istid’â itmeleriyle istid’âlarma izin ve ruhsat verilmesi hatt-ı şerif-i ‘inâyet redifim şudorma muhtâc olmağla mzsâ’ade-i ‘aliyyem emr-i şevâb idüğini mevlânâ-tı mumaileyh memhuren Tlâm itmeğin... ICR, No:51.

^^hatt-ı humâyün-ı şevketmakrünum mücebince baş muhasebeye kayd olunmağla imdi mucibince ‘amel olunmak babmda fermân-ı ‘alişânıra sadır olmuşdur. ICR, No:51.

^^öediği dahi zimmi-i mesfürun üzerine talulr ve hazine-i ‘âmirem defterlerine kayd olunmağla... ICR.No:51.

^5

Page 56: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

1001(1592), reveals an order to the Yeniçeri Ağası: In the past and since, the imperial

bread and simid bakery has employed 60 bakers, however, during the last 2-3 years,

some of the bakers have been expelled from the guild, while others have died. This has

reduced the number o f bakers employed, to 30. This number is insufficient for the

efficient functioning of the imperial bakery. Consequently, 15 workers have been

immediately appointed to the bakery.

Another recorded case dated Evasit-i Cemaziye'l-ewel 1226 (1181)^’ indicates

that new bakeries that were established without proving the need for an extra bakery,

have been closed down by government action. In early nineteenth century, although the

bread production in Pendik Karyesi ( Pendik) of Istanbul was sufficient both for the

residents as well as for the passers-by, a new bakery was established. A zimmi named

Nikoli had established an illegal bakery and had begun production and sale over

whatever price he wished, without abiding by the fixed official narb.^^ By these actions,

he ran against the rules of the bakers, and consequently he was complained about by

the bakers at kadi’s court. The bakers petitioned for the prohibition-closing o f Nikoli's

bakery. The issue was inspected by the kapan naibi Süleyman Muhiddin.” As a result

o f official scrutiny, the old bakery of Pendik village was deemed sufficient to meet the

MD, Vol: 69, 559-381.

” DHİDNo:17, 142: O. N. Ergin, Mecelle:W).

’^Pendik karyesinde vâki’ kadim olan bir bâb habbâz fuım karye-i mezbûr ahâlisine ve murür-ı ubür iden ibâdullaha kâfi vü vâfi iken karye-i mezburede nân-ı ‘aziz tabh ve l ’raâl eylemek üzere Nikoli nâm fimmi bir ‘aded habbâz fırmı inşâ ve bey’ ü fürüht birle şurüt-ı nizâmlarımn inhilâlini mOcib idüğinden... DHID, No: 17.

^^Fum-ı mezkûrun sedd ü bendiyçün emr-i şerifim şudOrunu istid’â eyledikleri cihetle husüs-ı mezbu r müderrisin-i kirâmmdan hâlâ kaban nâibi olan Süleyraân Muhiddin zide ‘ilmuhoya havâle olundukda. DHID, No: 17.

¿16

Page 57: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

requirements o f the residents,^* The purpose of Nikoli in opening a new bakery was

considered as an act of "profiteering" ( Cclh-i mâl: m âl topkmak)^^^ With the

announcement of the kadi , this illegally established bakery was closed down by an

imperial order,

According to a record of early eighteenth century, in the Valide-i ‘Atık Fırını®'

has etm ek (pure white bread of high quality) was produced. The establishment

possessed 18 stools of bread-sale in the past. The sales licence for each of these stools

was officially recorded according to the gedik practice.®^ Meanwhile, a court decision

was issued saying that in the Ibrahim Paşa Çarşısı ( Ibrahim Paşa Market) at

Silivrikapisi, sales at the stool near the shop of the Pazarcı were prevented.®'

Following a petition about this prevention, an imperial order was given to the kadi

instructing to guarantee the continuity of the sales at the above-mentioned stool.®‘‘

Similarly, the practice of havâ’ı gedikhas been documented in some other areas in the

eighteenth century. One record concerns the itinerant sales of the bread produce of a

bakery o f Arnavud Karyesi. The document constitutes an answer to the petition

58·Karye-i ınezbürede kadım olan bir ‘adcd habbâz fırınında ı ’ınâl olunan nân-ı ‘aziz karyc-i mezbure ahâlisine ve murür-ı ubür iden ibadullaha kâfi vü vâfı olmakla kat’iyyen ahar fırın ihdasına muhtaç olmayub... DHID, No: 17.

^^azla kazanç sağlamak, (obtaining excessive profits)

®”Nikoli zimminin muhdes olarak bu d efa inşa’ etmiş olduğu fıriın-ı mezkurun ma’rifet-i şer’le sedd ü bendi hususuna mübâderct ve hilafından miicancbet eylemeniz babında... DHID, No: 17.

'’'Evail-i Safer 1112 ( 1700 ) Divan-ı Humajaın Mühimme Defteri no; 111 ,0 , N. Ergin, Mecelle. “ The sale of a particular bakery’s produce on stools placed at different areas was a variety of the havâi gedik practice.

“ Vâlide-i ‘atık fuuni dimekle ma’rOf kadimden nân-ı hâş tabh olunan finimfl kadimi isleinlelerinden Sultan Mehmed Hân câmi’-i şerifi kurbunda Karamân-ı sağır ve Karağümrük çarşusunda çörekçi fırunı kurbunda ve iki bağçe kurbunda ... on iken etmekciler kethüdası tarafmdan Sili\ri Kapusı dâhilinde İbrahim Paşa çarşusında pazarcı dükkanma mutaşşıl olan iskemlede nân bey’ine mümâ’anet ve te’addi olunduğu i ’lâm olumnağın... DHMD, No:l 11.

®'Fıriin-ı mezküruft kadimi iskemlelerinde kadimisi üzere nân-ı haş bey’ine mümâne’et olunmıya deyO ...D H M D ,N o:lll.

A7

Page 58: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

submitted by zimmi Dimitraki who was the mutasarrıf o f the bakery gedik of a

francala fır ın ı in Arnavud Karyesi. In this petition, Dimitraki has demanded

permission for ten mobile peddlers who would operate in the area from Rumelihisarı

up to Beşiktaş. This fact seems to reflect how such havaT gediks granted to sellers

called gezdirici or kiifeci-tablakar were permitted to work. It can be said that the

criteria of permission for new gediks included a two-dimensional calculation. One side

o f the evaluation involved considering the demand and needs of the community for

manufactured goods. The other side involved the subsistence and the well-being o f the

artisans. The mobile gedik introduces an additional aspect to this evaluation which is

the concern for the efficient and thorough distribution of bread to the community. In

the above-mentioned document, the demand of Dimitraki has been summarized, and

parallel to most of the documents that have been examined concerning the gedik issue,

the related evaluation has depended on the testimony submitted at the presence o f the

kadi of Istanbul. The speakers at the court whose testimonies have determined the

decision are: the kethüda of the bread-makers, all nizam ustaları (masters in charge o f

the regulations) and the ihtiyarlar (elders). According to their testimony, bread

produced at the previously established bakery of Arnvudköy had to be sold by itinerant

peddlers gezdirici {küfeci-tablakars) in market places, bazaars and inside m a^lles.

Thus, similar to other bakeries, this bakery has been officially allowed to have

ten küfeci tablakar.*’ This practice enabled an official distribution o f the bread produce

® Bir bâb francalacı frrünmda tabh ·e ‘ibadullaha furüht ideceği francaladan on nefer tablakarlar yediyle Rumili hisarından Beşiktaşa gelince ‘ibadullaha francala bey’ ü şiralarına kimesne tarafuıdan muhalefet olunmamak içün yedine emr-i şerifim i ’tâsmı istid’a itmeğin ... DHMD, No: 111.

®®Mahrüse-i Galata’ya muzâf Beşiktaş nahiyesine tabi’ Ama\Tidkaryesi’ne hatt-ı humayün-ı ‘inâyetmakrOnumla biceddeden bina \ e inşa olunan francala fırûnunda tabh olunan nan-ı ‘azizin tablakârlar ile esvâk ve pârAr ve mahallât aralarında ğezdirilüb ‘ibadullaha bey’ olunması lazıme-i halden olmağla fırOn-ı mezkûra dahi sâ’ir fırancala fırunlarına ta’yin olunduğu gibi on ‘aded küfeci tablakâr ta’yin olunub... DHMD, No: 111.

66

Page 59: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

of Istanbul bakeries, by a fixed number of tablakars who shared the mahalles among

themselves. According to the shares, ten mobile sellers of the Beylerbeyi bakery were

to sell their produce along the area from Anadolu Kavak Hisarı up to Kadıköy; ten

street peddlers of the Ayazma bakery, along the area from Kadıköy to Anadolu Hisarı,

and ten itinerant peddlers, in the area from Tophane to Rumeli Kavak Hisarı. A kadi

decision was announced concerning the area lying between Tophane and Rumeli

Kavak Hisarı, according to which the street peddlers from the bakeries o f Üsküdar,

Beylerbeyi and from other bakeries o f the Anatolian side o f the Bosphorus were

forbidden to pass to the aforementioned area. The decision was given to the hands of

Dimitraki who had submitted a petition to the Divan-i Humayun previously. According

to the court announcement, an imperial order was to be issued which would state that

the two bakeries with their tablakars were sufficient to carry out bread sales in the area

from Rumeli Kavak Hisarı to Tophane. In case a mobile salesman from some other

bakery appeared in this area, he would immediately be captured by the zabit (policing

officials), and ustas (masters) and be sentenced to Arürc/r punishment^’ at the Tcrsaoc-

i  m ire imperial maritime arsenal).

Another example shows how the practice of gezdirici-tablakar was limited

according to certain criteria. This particular example is about the special case of

bakeries that operated to provide for the scfarethanes (embassies) of Istanbul. In 18

Safer 1230 (1815), there were 33 francala bakeries in Istanbul. All others had been

prohibited to operate. The production o f okkalık francala bread was allowed only at

six special bakeries including the Selimiye bakery which were producing particularly

*’Which involved hard labor.

®*Eğer karşu tarafdan ve sair fırunlardan akıntı burnuna ve gayri işbu iki fıruna mahşüş raevaki’den bir mahalle gezdirici ve küfeci ğelür ise bilatvakkuf ¿abitan ve ustalara haber virildikde ahz ve küreğe vaz’ içün tersane-i 'âmireme irsal olumnak üzere irsal l ’lârm mücebince... DHID, No: 18.

¿.9

Page 60: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

for the embassies. Among these bakeries, Selimiye Bakery had 20 gezdiricis.^^On the

other hand, the six bakeries which were to provide for the embassies were only

permitted to sell bread at their dest-gabs ( workshops).

This is a restriction brought about by considering that the six bakeries would

sufficiently meet the bread need of the embassies. Therefore these bakeries were not

allowed to have mobile gediks to distribute their production in Istanbul.

According to a record o f the end of July, 1708, o f the Bursa court records, the

kadi o f Bursa has sent a letter to Istanbul saying that the bakers of the town o f Bursa

were considered to be essential figures for the town as payers o f army provision dues,

(ordu akçası) in times of war, and other refcf///payments, and as gedikli providers o f

bread.’ Some residents o f Bursa had been baking bread at home and selling their

produce to others, at the marketplace.’“* This constituted a tlireat for the well-being o f

other words, the bakery had the licence for 20 havai gediks.

™Asitane-i ‘aliyye ve bilad-i sülüsede b i’l-ciimle francalacı fuainlarmdan inahall-i ma’lumede vâki’ otuzüç bâb francalacı fuoını ibka ile ma’dâsınıfl men’i ve okkalık francala Selimiye Fırumyla elçilere mahsus ibkâ kılınan altı 'aded fırunlara mahsus ve Selimiye fırumnm yignni nefer gezdiricileri gezdirüb ... DHID, No: 18.

^'According to established rules of the past, one dirhem of francala bread cost 2/3 of one dirhem of pure white-bread. In 1815, two paras of sacred bread was 68 dirhems. CK er the calculation of 2/3 , four paras of francala would be cooked as 91 dirhems and okkalık francala s price would be calculated over vuldyye’s price which was 32 paras After these calculations of the proper weight amd price of okkalık francala, the artisans were asked to be content with a little profit. As a result, the esnaf put fonvard the multitute of their expenses and demanded the forgiving of three dirhems out of 91 dirhems. Consequently, francala of the Selimiye bakery ( where four paras of francla was to be cooked at 88 dirhems 91-3=88) at the workshops and would be sold by mobile sellers at 28 paras.

^'Ve sa’ir ibka buyurulan firunlarda tabhinn’i babında şeref-efzâ-yı şalnfe-i şudur olan mübarek hatt- 1 humayun-ı şevket-makrüm şahane mücebince sadır olan fermân-ı ‘âllşâna imtişâlen...DHİD No. 18.

^^Brusa’da vaki’ habbaz ta’ifesi seferler vukü’unda ordu akçasm ve sa’ir tekalif eda ve her bar ahall- i şehre üzere tabh-ı nân ve ki-fayete müte’ahhidler ve kefillerin gedik sahibi ustaları olub şehirde eşedd-i ihtiyaçla lüzOmlarm mukarrer iken... BCR, No:65.

■’ba’zı kimesneler evlerinde etmeği tabh ve çarşu -pazarda âhara bey’ ve koltukçuluk etmeleriyle...BCR No:65.

50

Page 61: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

the bread-makers as well as an act against the valid rules of the locality/^ For this

reason, a court hüccet and a sultanic order were previously issued, prohibiting such

practices/^ Since this warning did not suffice to prevent these producers, a consensus

was reached with the participation of the notables of the town of Bursa, and the

breadmakers. A nine signatured hüccet was announced. According to this document,

the non-licenced koltukcu producers were obliged to produce each akçahk bread at a

7730 dirhem higher weight.

2.2 Conclusion

Gedik, which has been defined as 'usufhict over a work premise' or 'licence to

practice a certain trade', was born o f a necessity that appeared in the early eighteenth

century environment. The traditional structure of artisans was harmonized with the

interests o f the state and the registration of artisans' names, with their tools and their

workshops became a widespread practice Gedik, in fact was a complex phenomenon

in relation to the intersecting property rights where the interested parties were the

state, waqfs, and the artisans themselves.

Preserving gedik in one's hand was contingent upon meeting certain

requirements determined by the artisans' regulations. In the case of bakers, these

requirements included flour storage; baking pure, white bread of the proper quality and

weight; making payments to flour merchants at the right time; having guarantors and

’’Ta’ife-i mezbürenia (habbâz) perakende ve perişan olmalarına bâ’is olub nizam-ı beldeye halel virmekle... BCR, No:65.

^®mukaddemâ, bir iki d efa hüccet-i şer’iyye ve fermân-ı ‘âlı ile men’ olunmuşken... BCR, No;65.

’’koltukcu tâ’ifesi habbâz tâ’ifesiniö narhınıfi her bir akçahk etmekde otuz dirhem ziyâde işlemek üzere mu’ahede ve ittifak olduğunu... BCR, No:65.

51

Page 62: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

being recorded in defters. Fulfilling these requirements were partly detected by the

kapan nâibi records and the quality requirement was followed by the muhtesib/*

Considering the market mechanism, it can be said that granting gediks

depended on the needs of the population. In case of excess demand from the local

population, opening new bakeries was allowed. At the same time, opening bakeries

without licence was strictly forbidden. Excess supply was just as undesirable as leaving

the population without their daily bread. In order to distribute bread to the residents,

further measures were taken by the state, such as granting mobile gediks.

Not all gediks were abolished, in practice, following the Anglo-Ottoman

Commercial Treaty as the monopolies were left. Bakers' monopoly remained as an

exception that survived along with tobacco and flour monopolies.

78As will be touched upon in the next chapter.

52

Page 63: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

/ went to his bakery. I had his bread weighed and found it light. His

oven was still red hot. I had him thrown in, and my busine.ss was

finished... H is theft was a public theft that fe ll upon the most miserable

portion o f the people, those who buy their bread by the pound. You

approve o f the fate o f the th ief who robs the safe o f a financier and is

broken on the wheel, but you don't want me to burn the criminal who

robs the bread o f the poor. '

- - A Turkish kadi reported to Empress Catherine by Diderot. ^

CHAPTER III

QUALITY AND PRICE INSPECTION {IHTISÂD)

3.1 Application in 'Bread'

This section will be an attempt to comprehend and to explain the institution of

ibtisab and the duties and functions of the state officials responsible for the imposition

of this institution in Ottoman towns. For this purpose, the analysis will be developed

with emphasis on the regulation of price and quantity concerning "bread", in the light

of a primary source- "Resm -i ihtisabiyye tabşlliae sâdır olan emr-i şe r if dated

1243/1828.^ This imperial order concerning the ihtisab tax of Ankara comprises

extensive detail on the nature o f the market price determination and quality control

'Paul Ledieu, (1920)ed., “Observations sur l ’instruction de l ’Impératrice de Russie aux députés pour la confection des lois (17 7 4 )” Revue d'histoire economique et sociale 8, Paris: 392, cited by Kaplan(1996): 471-72.

-It should be noted that as documentary research has shown, Ottoman punishment method practiced in similar cases did not involve such brutality. As mentioned below, from chronicals nizamnames, as well as from miniatures, we know that guilty bakers would be caned in front of others. This quotation may have referred to a single criminal case, or most probably it must contain some exaggeration. In any case, it reveals the importance attached to the issue.

53

Page 64: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

mechanism; on its religious basis; on the responsibilities of inubtesib (the government

official for ihtisab) and on the fiscal aspect of the ihtisab tax, At the same time, the

document reflects some particularities of the 19th Century Ottoman Economy, Our

analysis will thus include occasional references to 19th Century characteristics. For our

purposes, the document will be scrutinised considering the legal and the fiscal aspects

o f ihtisab, as reflected in the duties o f muhtesib. The legal aspect will be demonstrated

by differentiating between Shar‘i and 'örfi ( A. ' ur f i : sultanic/customary) duties of the

muhtesib. These duties enlisted in the document will be grouped accordingly. The

fiscal aspect will be handled considering the above-mentioned peculiarities o f the 19th

Century Ottoman Economy.

The Imperial order dated 1243/1828 has been directed towards three officials

o f Ankara. These officials are the naib, mütesellim, and the muhtesib of the town.

The naib of the town was the judge, imposing Shar'i law of Islam. In each case o f a

crime or misdemeanour, his decision would be necessary to execute the corresponding

punishment. The mütesellim was responsible for the reinforcement of Sultanic Law in

a locality.“* The third official whose name has been mentioned in the document is the

muhtesib of Ankara. Looking at the document, it can be said that this office used to be

held bervech-i emânet, i.e. the official was appointed as the supervisor {emin) of the

ihtisab tax. He was responsible to collect the tax and send it to the treasury within

every tax period. Three ways of tax collection in the Ottoman fiscal system were first,

emânet as explained above; second, İltizâm Usûlü which meant that tax income of

^ACR,No;228-123.“*¥11061 Özkaya, in his (1977) Osmanh İmparatorluğunda Ayanlık, DTCF Yay, Ankara, has anah’zed that the post of mütesellimlik constitutes the basis of the strengthening of local notables during the 18th Century. There are numerous examples of â'yans who have originated from mütesellimlik. The people appointed as mütesellim during the eighteenth century onwards, were mostly chosen among the local people.

5/i

Page 65: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

one year from a particular tax source (mal) would be auctioned out to the highest

bidder. This person would thus become the mültezim. The transaction of the iltizam

ıısiilü was called mukata'a. Later, the term acquired the meaning of the "tax source"

itself The profit margin o f the mültezim would usually be fixed at the Islamic profit

limit of 10-20%; and usually at 15%. The mültezim was not allowed to raise the

auction price, unlimittedly. Moreover, he was required to have two guarantors {kefil

Ы'1-та1шА k e fil Ы'п-aefs). The difference between emanet and iltizam bk rested in

the down-payment of a quarter made in advance in the case o f iltizamlik. This down-

payment which was useful to meet immediate needs of the treasury, made the iltizam

usulü comparably desirable for the state; The third tax collection method was the

einin-i m ültezim ük usulü which was a mixture of these two practices.’ This document

indicates that emanet was the old practice used in the town of Ankara, however,

probably due to the above-mentioned reason and the inclination towards the iltizam

practice, the last situation in the town of Ankara reflects the traces of the iltizâm, or

the employment of an em ia-i mültezim . As put forward by Ariel Salzmann, following

the transitional period of fiscal transformation, iltizam practice stood out in which the

state had the role of the distribution of certain rights related to fiscal practices. "More

enduring than the legacy of early Ottoman fiscal and military- administrative centralism

was the achievement of a legal-administrative system of checks and balances that

contained provincial power building and reinforced the state's central role as the

distributor of rights, special privileges, stipends, offices, and immunities."®

^Sahilliğlu, Halil, (1962-63) " Bir Mültezim Zimem Defterine Göre XV. Yüzyıl Sonunda Osmanlı Darphane Mukataalan,"/FA/, XXIII (1-2),

®Ariel Salzmaım, "An Ancien Regime Revisited: 'Pri\ atization’ and Political Economy in the Eighteenth Century Ottoman Empire," Politics and Society, V:21. No:4, December 1993: 393- 423:397.

55

Page 66: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Looking at the people addressed in the document, (the na’ib, the mütesellim

and the muhtesib) it can be said that these three officials were responsible for the

reinforcement of the ihtisab regulations and the collection of the ihtisab tax. (muhtesib

in particular). But in fact, what were the ihtisab regulations and the ihtisab tax'i’ What

was their legal basis and the way of legitimisation employed by the state? It is possible

to extract solid evidence out of the document in question. The religious orders o f al-

'Am r bi'I M a'riif w a’a-nahy 'an i ’l-M uakar constitute the legal basis of these

regulations and taxes. The literary meaning of this Qur'anic phrase is "Promote good

and forbid evil" directed towards the Muslim community.’ This duty is considered to

be " the basic foundation o f the good conditions (well-being) fo r the World and the

people living in the World'"^ The duty mentioned above is the basis of the

responsibilities of the muhtesib.

In this document, there is a revision of the ihlisab rules concerning the town of

Ankara. The reason behind this revision is said to be the fact that Sultanic L.aw and

administrative regulations have been neglected and forgotten.'“ This neglect has

included the ihtisab issue, as well." Consequently, in other towns as Istanbul, Edirne,

İzmir and elsewhere, the ihtisab administration was reconsidered so that the ihtisab

regulations were improved. At this point, it might be meaningful to recall that in

1242/1826, a short while before this document was written, ministry of ihtisab as an

'Claude Cahen, "Hişba,"£'/2: 485.

'*"Şalâh-ı hal-i 'âlem ve 'âlemiyânın üss-i esâsı olan emi-i ma'rüf ve nehy-i 'ani'l-münker ahkâmının icrası zımnında vaz' ve tahsis kılınmış olan kanün-ı ihtisab..." ACR . No:228-123

’"...esâs-ı me'mOriyyetin olan emr-i ma'rüf ve nehy-i 'ani'l-münker ahkâmını..."ACR No:228-123.

'°"...kavânin-i 'örfiyye ve ni:^mat-ı mülkiyyeye layıkıylc bakılamış olduğundan..." ACR No; 228- 123.

IIm .kânün-1 ihtisab dahi külliyen metruk ve mensiy kalmış olduğundan..."ACR No: 228-123.

56

Page 67: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

administrative unit was established in Istanbul. This unit was under the supervision of

the ihtisab Minister who continued to administer ihtisab issues until the establishment

of şehremaneti in 1271/1854.*^

The legal nature of the aforementioned revision is inherent in two categories.

One is the emphasis placed upon SharT duties of the muhtesib concerning the

maintenance o f peace and order in the society. The other category is the market

regulatory mechanism that is to be imposed by controlling the fixed narh prices,

weights and measurements. This is the 'örfi duty of the muhtesib. He is responsible for

the punishment of the ones who run against the regulations, with the help of the kadi

(or naib in this case), and the mü tesellim, (to protect the people from injustice and

oppression). In official Ottoman documents, the term fukara’ is often used to indicate

all the people living in an Ottoman town. These people are in need of the protection o f

the sultan according to the Ottoman world view and the traditional conceptualisation

of "justice". The re’aya,- meaning 'flock'- were given to the Sultans by God, in trust.”

The concern over justice was centred around and premised on the protection of the

re'aya from oppression that could be exerted by the state officials-the military class,

particularly in the form of illegal taxation

This protection is executed by the administrators of the Sultan in the provinces,

the muhtesib, mütesellim and kadi. Traditionally, the ideal person who would be

employed as muhtesib would be a free, Muslim male with integrity, insight, reverence,

and social status. He would possess a profound knowledge o f the Sharl'a, moreover, a

knowledge of social customs and moors. 'Ilm (knowledge), Rifq (kindness) and Sabr

'^Claude Cahen: 485.

'^In some Ottoman documents, the people o f the country are referred to as "re'aya Id vedayi-i halik-i kibriyadu·" meaning 'entrusted to the safe keeping of rulers (sultans) by G od'.

57

Page 68: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

(patience) were considered to be important qualities that a muhtesib would possess.'^

According to our document, this person has to be both religious, (having the

knowledge of religion, well, diyanetkar) as well as adroit and resourceful (kârgüzâr).

The approach to the classification o f the functions/duties of the muhtesib based on the

work of Ibn Taymiya (on the institution of hisba) has considered these functions in

three categories, namely 1. those relating to the rights of God 2. those relating to the

rights of people 3. those relating to both.'^ Our approach, here, is to classify the

functions o f muhtesib as Shar‘i and 'örfi. In the Islamic community, custom is allowed

to be used in judicial matters not defined in religious law (A. shar') ; for example, in

circumstances related to hisba and the financial authority.*^ As put forward by Ibn

Taymiya, leadership in Muslim society requires the performance of special duties by

the rulers, in order to attain justice. Justice is established through proper knowledge

and the responsibility of the rulers towards the community.

Within this moral and religious structure, the functions of the muhtesib may be

perceived in two categories. The 'örfi duties of the muhtesib are basically those

concerning the market order; price determination; imposition of these prices; control of

the market prices and the quality of the goods sold; collecting the ihtisab taxes on the

commodities bought and sold in the market or on the commodities that come from

other places into town. These functions and duties are:

'"Halil İnalcık (1973/1994): 66-68.‘^Mohammad Akram, Khan, "Al-Hisba and the Islamic Economy," (Appendix: 135-148) to: Public Duties in Islam, The Institution o f the Ifisba by al-Shayk al-Imam Ibn Taymiya (1982/1402A. H.) (Translated from the Arabic by Muhtar Holand), The Islami Foundation, UK: 137-138.

'®al-Mawardi, Ahkamal-Sultaniyya: 243, quoted in Mohammad Akram Khan's Appendix to Ibn Taymiya (I982/I402A. H.): 138.

nIbn Taymiya (1982/1402 A. H .): 24-25.

Page 69: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

To prevent any hindrance to the order of a r t i s an s .To assure that all groups

of artisans carry out their own tasks, s e p e r a t e l y . T o protect the re'âyâ from

oppression and injustice.^* To decide on the ihtisab tax which will be imposed

moderately, (justly) according to the example o f each artisan group in other cities of

the Empire, (according to the taxes imposed with the renewed ihtisab kanunu in other

towns such as Istanbul, Edirne, Bursa and Izmir) To count and record all the shops,

commercial khanns and bathhouses and prepare a defter including corresponding taxes

on these establishments in a moderate way. To raise the amount of ihtisab tax

imposed on cattle coming to town towards November. To charge ihtisab tax from

caravan loads of various goods such as firewood, coal and lumber. To charge tamğa

resmi (stamp tax) from goods that have reached town without being stamp-taxed

elsewhere To collect the bac-j ¿aza/(m arket tax) and beytü'1-mâl (bayt al-mal)

erbiib-1 hiref ve şanâyinin şiraze-i nizam ü intizamlarına halel (alan-uk etmeyerek" ACR No:

228-123,

19," ..her bir sınıf kendünün kar ii kisb ve maşlahatiyle iştigâl..." ACR No: 228-123.

" ehl-i ticaret ve ehl-i hiıfetih derece-i hâl ve keyfiyyetlerine ve ol tarafıh usul ü ahvâline göre her bir sınıfdan emşâline tatbikan benech-i i'tidâl resm-i ihtisâb lüsümu ma’rifet-i şer’ ve esnaf kethüdâları ma’rifetiyle yegân yegân tahkik ve şebt-i defter olunarak ta’dil ve tcsviyye usulüne ri’âyetle kararlaşdırılub" ACR No: 228-123.

derun-ı şehrde kâin bi’l-cümle dekâkin ve han ve hamam ve sâireyi ma’rifet-i şer’-i şerif ve cümle ittifâkıyle yegân yegân taham ve tahkik ile her birine hadd-i i ’tidalde tahşiş kılınan ı*üsum-ı ihtisâbiyyenih "ACR No: 228-123

bi'l-cümle ahâli-i memleket ve fukarâ-yı ra’iyyetin kemâl-i asayiş ve istirahat ve ğadr ü hayfdan hiraâyet ve şiyanetleri kaziyyesi istihsâl kılınmak (içün)" ACR No:228-123.

medine-i raezkûreye ruz-ı kasım takarrübünde basdınnalık olarak tevârüd eden kara sığırın beher re’sinden kadimden alınağelen dörder para resm-i ihtisâba münâsibi mikdâr zam ve ilâve olumnası" ACR No: 228-123.

^^"...li-ecli’t-ticâre gelen karbân hamulelerinin emti’âsına göre beher yükünden ve hatab ve kömür ve ecnâs-ı kerâsteden münâsibi veçhile resm-i ihtisâb ..."ACR No: 228-123.

“■" "...mahal-i sâireden resm-i tamğa almmamış ise eşmânından beher ğuruşa birer para resm-i tamğa ..."ACR No: 228-123

59

Page 70: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

taxes that are included in the ihtisab mukata’asi o f Ankara. To control and lead the

craftsmen o f the town. To fix the values of all goods, foodstuffs, and drinks with the

co-operation and supervision of kadi, mütesellim, all the people that are concerned

(and muhtesib himself). To do this in a moderate way. To make sure that goods are

not sold above the fixed price. ** To go out and check all the weights used by the

artisans. To punish the ones who have been engaged in trickery, or those that charge

high prices, by beating with the cane, (see the diagram)^^ To sentence the ones that

have committed greater crimes to ihtisab habsi. (imprisonment)'’** To imprison those

that deserve, in the castle and after the completion of their punishment, to set them free

without demanding any extra charges.’'To make sure that no one sells goods above

the fixed price or using fraud measuring utensils.’ Especially to see to the

importance of keeping the weight and the price of sacred bread’’ at the proper fixed

medıne-i mczkürede kain dekakın ve sa’iroden raahşüş olan rüsUın-ı ihtisabiyye ile mukata’a-i mezkürenifl rüsüınât-ı kadımesiyle tevabi’inden olan bac-ı bazar ve beytü’l-mal rüsumatını vakt ii zamaniyle ahz ü tahsil ..."ACR No. 228-123

eşya ve erzakın sennayesi ına’rifetin ve hakimüş-şer’ ve mütesellim ve sa’ir ı ’rifetiyle bi’t-taharri vaktine göre icab eden fiyatı hadd-i i ’tidal üzere vaz edeı

ACR No: No; 228-123.

■ "...cemi gelenler ma’rifetiyle

lazım derek ..."

narh-ı fiyat-ı mukarrereden ziyâdeye bir nesneye bey’ ü fürüht edememeleri ..." ACR No: 228- 123.

■'^"...kola çıkub her ne kadar terâzu ve kantar ve mikyal ve arşun ve endaze ile ahz ü i ’tâ eder eşnâf vâr ise cümlesinin vezn ve kiyel ve arşun ve endazelerine ihale-i enzar-ı dikkat ederek noksan zuhur edenlerin eşhâbmı iktizası veçhile değnek çlarbiyle ta’zlr ve tekdir ..." ACR No: 228-123.

“"...bundan ziyâdece te’dlbe müstehak olanları ihtisâb habsine ilkâ..."ACR No: 228-123.

^'"...kal’aya müstehak olanları hâkimüş-şer’ ve mütesellim ma’rifetiyle kafaya vaz’ ile ışlâh-ı nefs eylediklerinden sonra raeccânen sebilleri tahliyye olunub zinhar bir kimesneden cerâim alınmaması..."ACR No: 228-123.

noksan vezn ile veyâhud narh-ı fiyât-ı mukarrereden ziyâdeye bir nesneye bey’ ü füriiht edememeleri..." ACR No: 228-123.

‘ nân-ı ’aziz" ACR No: 228-123.

6(

Page 71: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

levels. ‘*To make sure that the meat sold by butchers is sold at the proper price and

w e i g h t . T o make sure that porters charge porter fees for the goods they carry,

j u s t l y . T o make sure that lumber, lightwood, coal, vegetables and goods as such are

bought and sold at the fixed prices. To search every mahalle (quarter), çarşt-pazar

(market place), hanlar (khans/iims); find eveiy shop and room owned by merchants

and artisans and record every one o f them.^* To record anyone who is not among

merchants or artisans, but who carry out other types o f business in commercial

khans.‘^To prepare and to submit a record of expenses of the locality, every six

months, to the government in Istanbul.

At the same time, the muhtesib had religious functions as: In case o f the

marriage of the re'aya“” to charge ihtisab tax from these marriages according to the

·” " be-tahsis nan-i ’azizin sikke ve vezninin bozuk ve natamam olmaması emr-i ehemmine ..."ACR

No: 228-123.

kassablarm şayf ü çitada fürühl eyledikleri lalumn narh ve vezjıine..." ACR No: 228-123.

hammal ta’ifesinin bir mahalden bir mahale götürdükleri ahmal ve eşkalin ücret-i nakliyyesini hadd-i i ’tidalde vaz edüb ziyâde ücret almamaları."ACR No:228-123.

^\ereste ve hatab ve kömür ve sebze ve sâ’ir bu misillü eşya cümle ma’riletiyle ta’yın olunarak fiyatdan ziyâdeye bey’ ü fürtiht olunmaması. "ACR No: 228-123.

medıne-i mezkiirede kâ’in bi’l-cümle mahallât ve esvâk ve hanlar ve sâ’ireyi ma’rifetinle yegân yegân tahrir edüb seksnesinin şanâyi ve ism ü şöhretlerine ve hal ü iktidarlarına kesb-i vukuf ve ıttıla ile derûn-ı şehrde ka’in ve sa’ir hanlar deıiınunda ne mikdar dükkan \ e oda ve mağazaları vâr ise içlerinde olan tüccar ve esnaf maküleleri ma’rifetin ve hâkimüş-şer’ ve mütesellim ve esnaf kethüda ve yiğitbaşıları ma’rifetleriyle tahkik..."ACR No: 228-123.

’’"...tüccar %e eşnafdan ohnayub da hanlarında sakin olarak ceht-i uhra ile kâr ü kisbe sâlik olanlarıii hâl ü şanlarını dahi mahallât imamlarından ve sâ’ir ehl-i vuküfdan taharri ve tekik ile defler ederek bir sureti tarafında \e bir sureti dahi mahkemede hıfz olunmak "ACR No:228-123.

'’'^"...bundan böyle ·ukü bulacak memleket mesârifi defteri bu def’a 'adaleti muş’lr Anadolu ve Rumilinifi üçer kollarına ışdâr kılınığı veçhile beher altı mâhda bir kere tarafmdan ve hâkim ve mütesellim câniblerinden dahi bi’t-temhır der-i sa’âdelime takdim .."ACR No: 228-123.

"""re'âyâ" refers only to non-muslims as will be explained below.

Page 72: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

status of the c o u p l e s . T o prevent these communities, who have paid ruhsatiyye

charge from committing deeds contrary to Islamic community,·*^ To assure the

execution of the al-amr b i’l-ma‘rof w a’n-nahy ‘ani’l-munkar orders with the

cooperation and supervision of the kadi and mütesellim. To remind and reinforce

the performance of the Qvkat-i (daily prayers) five times a day, with the Muslim

community, (which was religiously compulsory only for the Muslims. )‘*^To go out to

control the execution of oruç (fasting) and namaz; warn the ones who neglect these

religious d u t i e s . T o see to the order o f the town and the well-being of the residents.

To prevent non-muslims from wearing green and red clothing (which are proper colors

for the muslims) and from covering their heads with white.“** To prevent non-muslims

from wearing peştem al (special bathhouse-clothing) and nalin (bath clog) so as to

differentiate between Muslims and non-mu slims.

For an interpretation of the ihtisab practice, to begin with, market control and

economic regulation may be considered. According to the Ottoman economic mind. 50

re’âyanıii gerdeği zuhurunda a’la ve evsat ve edna i ’tibariyle beherinden resm-i ihtisâb alınması..."ACR No: 228-123.

milel-i mezküreye dahi ruhşatiyye verdik diyerek zinhar belde-i islamiyyede hâriç ez tavr-ı rağbet harekete cevaz gösterihnemek... ACR No. 228-123.

esâs-ı rae’müriyyetin olan emr-i ma’ruf ve nehy ‘an i ’l-münker ahkâmını hâkim ü‘ş-şer‘ ve mütesellim marifetleriyle b i’l-ma’iyye icrâya...”ACR No:228-123.

mü’emmen ve muvaUıid olanlar (a) farz-ı kat’ı olan evkât-ı hamseyi cemâ’atle edaya müdâvemet eylemelerini ‘umümen tenbîh ve te’kid"ACR No:228-123.

aralık aralık derûn-ı memleketde kol gezerek şavm ve şalâtı târik ve menâhl münkerâta sâlik olanları iktizâsma göre ta’zir ve tehdide mübâderef'ACR No: 228-123.

'’’...beldenin tensik-ı nizâm ve sekenesinin terfih-i ahvallerine ihtimâm ü d i^ a t...”ACR No:228- 123.

^ ’’...re’âyâ makülesi ehl-i islâma mahşüş olan yeşil ve kınnızı eşvâb iktisâ etmetüb başlarma daW beyaz sarmamaları.”ACR no: 228-123.

Hamamlarda kefereye verdikleri peştemâl vesâ’irenift ehl-i islâma verilmemesi ve müslim ile kefere beyni fark ve temyiz içün kefereye na’lin ğiydirilmemesi."ACR No: 228-123.

6:

Page 73: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

control over artisans'guilds, trade and market prices was a significant aspect of the

continuity of production. Trade and artisanal production were providing the town

population of the empire as well as the army. Guilds and small peasants were part of

the same traditional structure, the continuity of which was reassured by the state. In

relation to this, Halil İnalcık has put forward that "The rules o f hisba were fitted to,

and upheld, the guild system and as such conformed to the classical Near Eastern ideal

of the state, which sought to protect the traditional class structure as being the

mainstay of social h a r m o n y . G u i l d regulations, following the confirmation o f the

52sultan, became an ihtisab law.

Within this framework, market price determination and its control was a major

issue carried out by the state. Together with the price control, quality control over

goods produced by artisans constituted the basis o f 'pre-industrial town economy'. In

this system, state control guaranteed the protection of both the producer and the

consumer. This mechanism was particularly valid in the Anatolian towns of the pre­

industrial era, where the market was limited. In such circumstances, Ottoman State

was economically oriented to fix prices at a moderate level so as to prevent

profiteering by merchants and craftsmen. Correspondingly, the quantity of production

would be limited in order to prevent too low market prices.

“Halil İnalcık, "Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects of the Ottoman Economy," in Cook, ed. ( 19 70 ).:20 7-2 1 8 ; Halil İnalcık, The Ottoman Empire the C lassical A ge 7500-/000,Phoenix paperback. 1994; Halil İnalcık ed. with Donald Quataert, (1994) An Econom ic and Social H istory o f the Ottoman Empire 1300-1914, Cambridge; Genç, Mehmet (1989) " Osmanh İktisadi Dünya Görüşünün ilkeieri," İstanbul Üniversitesi E debiyat Fakültesi Sosyoloji D ergisi, 3. Dizi, I.

^'Halii İnalcık (1969) " Capital Formation in the Ottoman Empire," JEH, XXIX ( I ) , NYU Press. : 106.

^-Halil İnalcık (1970): 216.

^ see Halil İnalcık (1980). "The Hub of the City: The Bedestan of İstanbul," UTS, I, Madison Wisconsin: 1.

63

Page 74: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

The carefully fixed market price was called the narh (P. narkh) price of

commodities. According to the chronicler “Âll, this institution was one o f the "major

issues"(umur-i kiilliyye) rather than one of the "minor issues"{umur-/ cüz'/) . Viziers,

judges and governors were obliged to place uttermost importance to this institution

and personally take interest in it. ® Ottomans did in fact consider the issue to be

significant and included narh controls among the duties of the grand vizier. The

institution thus survived until the mids of the 19th Century.” Inspection o f prices and

quality o f goods required a practice called ko/a çıkm ak (patrol) This was the personal

checking of the market place, prices, quality of goods sold and the weights and

measurements. ” This document dated 1243 includes the order of "kola çıkmak"

directed towards the muhtesib of Ankara. In Istanbul, during the Classical Age, this

task would sometimes be carried out by the grand vizie.-, the kadi o f Istanbul, Yeniçeri

Ağası (head officer o f janissaries) and the muhtesib . The regular controller of narh,

■‘'"An example of such a practice is the limit put on the number of workshops owned by Istanbul weavers in the 19th Century, as stated in the Divan-i Humayun Esnaf Defteri dated 1242 ( Halil İnalcık Collection. Bilkent University Central Library. Ankara) cited in the chapter on Gedik.

'^Osman Nuri Ergin (1338), M eeeH e-i Umur-/ B e le d iy y eI. , Istanbul: 560

^^Müverrih Ali, Fuşülü'l-haU vci-'akd, r e uşulüi-har ve'n-nakday/oied by Miibahat Kütükoölu (1983) OsmanlIlarda Narh M üessesesi ve 1640 tarihli N arh Defteri, Enderun Yay. İstanbul: 6.

■‘' Mübahat Kütükoğlu, (1983): 8.

■‘'’ Similarly, British government took interest in grain prices: "from 1771, of the average prices of the grains sold in monitored markets, so as to operate successive corn laws, and at local level up to 1836, w herever an Assize of Bread was set, of the average prices of grain or flour, ny which to determine ( and then record) the maximum lawful prices of loaves..." Petersen (1995): 182.

All Seydi Bey, in his Teşrifat ve teşkilat-/ kadimemiz, describes the practice of patrol among the duties of the grand vezir: (Reported by Tevkii Abdurrahman Paşa)Kanûn-ı kadim mûcebince kola çıkan sadrazam subaşı perişâm ve bekçibaşı süpürgesiyle yoldaşlarınn önüfie dizip kendüleri atbaşı beraber eşerler. Çardak çorbacısı süpürgesiyle ve şehir kâd'siniö kethüdası perişâm ile beraber giderler. Bufllan derğah-ı ‘Âli çavuşları, şehir kâdisi, yeniçeri ağası ta’klb eder. Ihtisab ağası vezir-i â ’zamm önünde şatırlannortasmda şaraçbâşı ile yürür. Bu zekilde saraydan çıkılub iskele yolundan gidilerek unkapamna uğranır. ... Daha sonra vezir-i 'Âzam at

6A

Page 75: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

however, was the muhtesib.^* The ihtisab kanunları *"’enable us to trace the continuity

of the price control mechanism beginning from the Classical Age until the 19th

Century.

We have so far touched upon the economic motivation behind state control,

however it would be improper to assume a homogeneous state interest in every type o f

commodity. Again, a pragmatic motivation can be found in the pattern o f strict price

controls of the Ottoman State. Halil İnalcık, in his "Capital Formation in the Ottoman

Empire" has referred to this distinction as: "Free trade in cereals and their export were

forbidden, in order to prevent profiteers from speculating in them and to prevent their

diversion to foreign markets."*^" In other words, the Ottoman State was exerting

pressure of control concerning strict necessities and practicing a relatively liberal price

regime concerning luxuries. In our document, we can observe the same pattern by

looking at the commodities whose prices have been fixed. These commodities are strict

necessities such as bread, lumber, coal, vegetables etc. whose quality and the

measurement utensils of sale also constitute an area of state intervention. The reason

behind such attention paid to the necessities reflects the "justice" concern of the Sultan

or the State: protection of the people from oppression and injustice; the provision o f

the population with their basic needs at moderate prices and at a good quality. "As the

staple food, one that was both 'of the greatest economic value' and 'viewed with

mystical respect', bread in France was under the control of the most important man in

“ lbid:19.

*'See Ömer Lütfı Barkan " XV. Asrın Sonunda Bazı Büyük Şehirlerde Eşya ve Yiyecek Fiyatlannın Tesbit ve Teftişi Hususlarım Tanzim Eden Kanunlar," Tarih Vesikaları, II 7 : 15-40; 9: 168-177 and Robert Mantran, (1995) XJ1.-XITI1. Yüzyıllarda Osnıanlı imparatorluğu Çev. M. A. Kıhçbay, İmge Yay: 139, Ankara, ch: 1; 13-58.

“ Halil İnalcık (1969): 119.

65

Page 76: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

the entire kingdom: the King himself. " ‘ In the King's name, the Grand Provost of

Paris had the bakery trade entrusted to him.*''*

Among the above-mentioned commodities, "bread" is probably the most

significant of all. This fact is also revealed, as seen in the document, by the term aaa-i

"aziz indicating bread Bread was the basic foodstuff feeding the low-income

population of the pre-industrial era. It also had the quality o f being religiously sacred

for the Muslim community. Similar to the hisba regulations o f the Ottoman Empire, in

France, there was strict control over the quality of flour and baking. As early as the

fourteenth century, Huber Collin has quoted a Charter of Beaumont in Argonne

specifying penalties:

The baker who bakes bread must do it properly, and it shall be of

marketable quality, well baked and made in accordance with the legal

standard, which states that it shall be made of the best wheat on the

market or within two deniers of that price. And if on the contrary, it is

found to be poorly baked or too small in size, the baker shall pay a fine of

five sols and the bread be given to the poor. And if it is found that he has

failed to have bread baked every 24 hours he shall pay the same fine... And

if it is the fault o f the man who tends the oven that the people's loaves

were not properly or sufficiently baked, then he shall repay the value of ten

loaves 66

Since bread was very important, so were the bakers providing the population

with b r e a d . B r e a d was thus a unique commodity that was subject to state control

*^MaguelonneToussaint-Samat (1987/1992): 234.

* lbid.

®^ACRNo. 228-123.

“ Maguellone Toussaint-Samat (1987/1992): 234.

66

Page 77: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

with its exceptional qualities.^*Again in France, the master baker had to obtain a

certificate o f his skill before he was allowed to establish a bakery o f his own. During

the second empire, and in the first days of the early republic the master baker, together

with the master fisherman were called maître. Both fish and bread were considered

"noble foods".

According to research put forward by Evangelia Balta on 'Bread in the Greek

lands during the Ottoman Rule', the price o f Bread would be determined by the mutual

agreement of the bakers, the kadi and other officials. The requests would be submitted

to the governor. He would refer to the kadi, who would invite all the people

concerned to decide ; the kethüda, muhtesib, and all the officials concerned would

record the narh price.™ This fixed price would be revised at least twice a year.(during

Rtiz-i Hizir and Ruz-i Kasim ) Occasional renewal of the price depended on the crop

®^Üsküdarh Aşık Razi reveals the indebtedness of the commumty that was felt towards the bread-

makers in his verses:

Öpillnıeve ¡ayıktır o ayaklar hilhas-sa H akkıdır gurur ile yalınayak .salınsa A ç kalırız cünıleten bu şehr-i İstanbul da Şehbazın ayakları hamuru yoğurma.sa

(Reşat Ekrem Koçu, (1971) "Ekmek. E\ımekç\\&x” İstanbul Ansiklopedisi, IX :4975.)

®*The sacred character of bread was as significant in the Christian World as it can be observed in the religious rituals:" Bread stood for the bod> within Christian symbolism. Makind and distributing bread carried profound connotations of friendship, communion, giving, sharing, justice- indeed, literally, companionship.” as Roy Porter asserts in the preface of B read o f D ream s by Piero Camporesi, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1989. On the other hand, the story of a Turkish sipahi is told by Fernand Braudel in The Structures o f E veryday Life ch:2 "Daily Bread,". The above-mentioned soldier was captured in 1688 by the Germans and was able to cook a dough- bread using his ration of flour and water, displaying greater dexterity than any other soldier. The indispensibility of bread for low-income population in different cultures is an issue that can be handled in a comparative perspective considering both the economic practices related to its production, distribution, price and weight as well as its culturally symbolic character.

«’Toussaint-Samat (1987/1992): 235.

^^Evangelia Balta (1994) " The Bread in Greek Lands During the Ottoman K\x\q,”AÜ D TCF Tarih Araştırm aları Dergisi, XVI, 27: 209.

67

Page 78: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

yield, financial situation, and political c hanges . The change in price due to the market

conditions would be reflected as a change in the weight o f a loaf of b r e a d . T h e

quality, the weight and the quantity supplied would be regulated and recorded by the

officials. For instance, in the Ramazan o f 1013, the quantity o f bread supplied by

bakers was recorded by the kadi of Ankara as:

oldur ki etmekçi Elhâc Mustafa’ya cânib-i şer'den her gün beş ağız

etmek işlenmek tenbih olundukda işlemeyüb tahallüf eyledüği subaşı

‘'Ali Beğ talebi ile Ahmed bin Mehmed ve üstad Muştafa bin .... Nâm

kimesneler şahadet eyledikleri kayd olundu.

By the kaauanâaıe-i ibtisâb-ı Bursa dated 1502, published by Ö. L. Barkan,

the control of the quality of bread has been based on a practice called çaşni dutmak.

This process was carried out by respectable people among the craftsmen.’' Following

this process, in Bursa, the price of bread was fixed considering the three qualities o f

flour According to the ihtisab kanunu., ;he standard bread had to be made from

sifted fine flour, well cooked; white and without odor or fragrance.'' In the same

iba/m/maine concerning the ihtisab o f Bursa, there are references to the trickery carried

out by bread-makers. Making bad quality bread is mentioned to be against the law and

the sharl'al 76

’Kütükoğlu (1983): 9; Balta (1994): 211; Mantran (1995): 327.

^^Balta(1994): 212.

’ ”Hakimü'l-\akt emriyle ehl-i hibreden mO'temed ve sika kişiler çaşni dutarlardı." see Ö. L. Barkan, "XV. Asnn Sonunda Bazı Eş>a ve Yiyecek Fiyatlarının Tesbit ve Teftişi Hususlannı Tanzim Eden Kanunlar," TV, II S:7. Bursa: 15-16

“'"Buğdaym a'lası yüz on akçaya evşâtı yüze ednâsı seksenbeş akçaya olsa etmek yediyüz dirhem bir akçaya olub bahada ziyade ya noksan olsa bu kıyas üzere aña dahi ta'yin oluna" Ibid; 16.

*"lnce elekden elene ve tamam bişe ve ak ola ve rayihası olmıya" Ibid.

^^"şer'den ve kânundan haris iş caiz değildir"Ibid.

6^

Page 79: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

In the kadi sicils of the town of Ankara, the weight and price o f bread are

recorded as:

budur ki Kasim bin 'Ömer nam etmekçinin etmeği vezn olunub narh

yüzyigrmi iken etmeği seksen dirhem geldiği kayd olundu^.77

budur ki Hızırbeşe bin 'Abdülhak etmeği vezn olundukda narh bir akçaya

yüzyigrmi dirhem iken bir akçaya yetmiş dirhem geldiği kayd şodd’*

budur ki Ankara’da olan etmekçi tâ’ifesi etmek huşûşıyçün biribirine

kefil olub hıyn-i lüzûmda ihzar içün ta’ife-i mezbûredera 'Öm er ve Şan

Ahmed ve Kabaca ve Hacı 'Ali ve Hacı Mustafa ve Hızır ve Ahmed ve

Hacı Mahmûd birbirinin nefslerine kefil olub hıyn-ı lüzûmda ihzara

ta‘ahhüd eyledikleri kayd şodd^’

The quality of bread was not to be determined by weight alone, as mentioned in the

kanunname. The record of an under-standard bread describes the dough of the bread to

be unpleasant “like mud .

budur ki Sari Hasan’in dükkanında işlenen etmek meclis-i şer'de vezn

olunub narh yüzyigrmi iken altmış dirhem geldiğinden mâ'da burçak ve

darı ve arpa karışmış deyû müslümanlar şahadet idüb ve hamın balçık

gibi olub ekli mümkün olmadığı bi’t-taleb kayd şodd*.80

At a later date, in 1220 (1805), narh requirement for Istanbul bakers was followed as;

Bundan akdem etmekçi esnafına bâ-ferman-ı ‘alı virilen narh-ı câriye

itâ’at ey-emeyüb ‘ibadullahı izrardan halı olmadıkları ecilden tebdil

çukadarları kulları ahz olunub Mahzlr Ağa kulları tomruğuna vaz‘ ü habs

’’5 Şewal 1013; ACRNo; IX-1323

5 Şevval 1013; ACRNo: IX-1322.

19 Şevval 1013; ACRNo: IX-1443,

«‘'ACRNo: IX-1315.

69

Page 80: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

olunduğu ma‘lüm -ı devletleri buyuruldukda emr ü ferman devletlü,

‘inâyetlü sultânım hazretlerinindir.

Apart from the price-regulatory aspect of ihtisab rules, the issue o f the weights

and measurements stands out to be an important component o f the ihtisab institution.

The measurement utensils that are mentioned in our document are accordingly, terazu,

kantar, m ikyal, arşun, endaze, vezn and kiyel. Halil İnalcık, in his "Introduction to

Ottoman Metrology" has touched upon weights and measures in relation to the ihtisab

issue, as follows:

Assaying and the periodical inspection of weights and measures was

considered one of the most important duties of the government since

the opinion of the populace was that shortages, high prices and famine

were often associated with the failure o f the authorities to check fraud

and abuses committed by merchants and traders...In İstanbul, two

officials kileci (assayer) and tamgaci (stamper) under the muhtesib

were constantly in charge of testing and certifying all kinds of measures

in use at the market. Using standard measures kept in the public

treasury the kileci did the job of assaying (ayar) and then the tamgaci

certified the correctness and validity by imprinting the official stamp

(miri tamga) on measures.'*^

«'CBNo: 878.

®‘Halil İnalcık (1983)" Introduction to Ottoman Metrology," Turcica, XV: 335.

7C

Page 81: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

3.2 The Fiscal Sphere- Taxation

The fiscal sphere is the mechanism of the imposition o f the ihtisab riistimu

(taxes) and the direction, or the use of this tax income, by the state. According to our

document, following the revision of the ihtisab regulations, the amount o f taxes

imposed has been raised.*’ The revenue to be collected as the ihtisab tax was to be

spent first, on the needs of the officials of ihtisab*“* and secondly and more

significantly, on the expenses of the newly established army by Sultan Mahmud II,

'Asakir-i Maosure-i M ubammcdiyye^^ This practice indicates a multi-dimentional

phenomenon reflecting the 19th Century political and economic transformation of the

Ottoman State specifically on the fiscal side Politically, the establishment of the new

army was the consequence o f the modernisation efforts since the abolishing of the

Janissary Corps in 1826 known as Vak'a-yi Hayriyyc. Ficonomically, this new

establishment necessitated further extraction of taxes by the government since the

salaries and other expenses would constitute a new burden on the treasury. To meet

these expenditures, a separate treasury called Maaşüre H azînesi had been

established.*'" Until the end of the 18th Century, the single-treasury system was valid,

however, during the 18th century, double-treasury practice was started an example for

which is the Manşüre Hazînesi. * The tax revenues that were sent to the Manşüre

Hazînesi have been listed in this document as beytii’l-mal (the properties which

^^".,.resm-i ihtisaba münasibi mikdâr zam ve ilâve olunması..." ACR No; 228-123.

*^"...ihtisâba me'mür olanların meşârif-i zarüriyyelerine..." ACR No: 228-123.

®^"...'Asâkir-i Manşüre-i Muhaımnediyye'nifi meşârif-i lâ-yuhşasınâ medâr olmak içün..." ACR No: 228-123.

*®Mübahat Kütükoğlu (1982) " Sultan II. Mahmut Devri Yedek Ordusu Redif-i Asakir-i Mansure," TED. XII, 149-150.

*'Cezar Yavuz (1986) Osnıanlı Mâliyesinde Btmalim ve Değişim Dö/jew/,İstanbul.

Page 82: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

reverted to the state because there were no heirs)**, bac-i bazar, resm-i tamğa, and

taxes seperately mentioned along with the related commodities to be taxed. Among

these taxes, bac-i bazar was levied on merchandise coming from outside and sold in a

market in the town, resm-i tamğa was levied on textiles and metals and other taxes

were taken according to the detail ordered in the emr-i şerif in question. *

The document reflects the bureaucratic side o f the application o f the double­

treasury system, as well. To meet the expenses of the new army, according to the

imperial order written from the Divan-i Hümâyûn, 'llmübabers (memos) have been

sent to the baş muhasebe (head-accounting office) as well as the zim m et defterleri of

the treasury. Baş Defterdar has approved of the situation and the m iim za (signed)

ihtisab Defteri has been recorded by the Dlvan-i Hümâyûn Kalemi. The muhtesib o f

Ankara has been given a copy of this record.

3.3 Conclusion

The analysis of a nineteenth Century Ottoman ihtisab document concerning the

taxation of the town of Ankara has shown that the ihtisab office of the town was held

according to the emin-i mültezim practice, by the official responsible for the

application of the rules of hisba: the muhtesib. The muhtesib was to regulate the

ihtisab rules within the framework of the shar‘i precepts of “ordering the good and

prohibiting evil.”

The duties and functions of the muhtesib within this picture were divisible into

two branches: The ‘örfi functions and the sharT functions. The former of these

®*Halil İnalcık (1980): 7.

«’Claude Cahen, "Hisba," £72:489.

Page 83: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

comprised of the economic regulations concerning market control. In this sphere, the

state intervention took place in the form of fixing the market prices (narlı), controlling

the quality of commodities sold, and checking the weights and measures used by the

providers of goods. These duties of the muhtesib were closely related to the regulation

and control o f artisans' quality of production. The motivation behind such state

intervention has been high, concerning strict necessities such as bread and meat; and

low, concerning luxuries. The fiscal aspect o f the ihtisab rüsumu, that is the direction

o f the tax income, involved the treasuiy that was newly established for the expenses o f

Sultan Mahmud II's reform army, ‘Asakir-i Mansxire-i Mubammediyye. The latter

category o f the fimctions of the muhtesib was the religious (şer’i) sphere. This aspect

concerned the order of the quarters (mahalles) of the town of Ankara, A

differentiation between Muslim and Non-Muslim residents was inherent in the clothing

regulation of the ihtisab rules. Moreover, the execution of religious duties such as

daily prayers and fasting were to be controlled by the muhtesib. Again, the tax income

from taxes such as religious head taxes and marriage-licence taxes was reserved for the

financing of the ‘Asakir-i Manşure.

In sum, the imperial order dated 1243/1828, concerning the ihtisab taxes and

regulations of the town of Ankara shows the survival of an institution of the Classical

Age of the Ottoman era, that has roots back in the Early Islamic Period. It is worth

noting that this institution has continued into the nineteenth Century, despite the

Empire's subjection to forceful capitalistic pressures as well as European-oriented

modernisation movements.

’“ACRN o; 228-123.

73

Page 84: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Ottoman Empire, with its gigantic size and strategic geography constituted a

"complex and multi-dimensional" structure, Ottoman economic policy was shaped by

government traditions of Iranian and Islamic origins. Iranian economic tradition implied

a strictly controlled, "state-managed" economy in which production of revenues for the

ruler played a significant part, Within this structure, justice was important to the extent

that it would help to keep the sultan's rule. The Islamic tradition perceived justice as an

end in itself, in other words, as the application of Godly justice, on Earth. The Islamic

ideal put emphasis on ethics of the marketplace. Excessive profits were forbidden.' These

two philosophies are said to have been compromised in the Ottoman legal implementation

of both kantin and shari‘a.^"Kanun rendered unto Caesar the fiscal affairs of the state,

while the shari'a rendered unto God the morality and ethics of the marketplace."^

Following the Classical Age, Ottoman government entered a period of decline,

which led the way to "fiscal corruption". At the same time this was a period of

mercantilism in pre-industrial Europe. Ottoman 'anti-mercantilist' decline was contrasting

the rise of capitalism in mercantilist Europe.·* Mercantilism was considered by Eli

Heckscher as "the economic system of nationalism," where the interests of the native

country were prior to those of all other nations and states. It was believed that,

dominance over other countries could be achieved through the weakening of rival

countries rather than the strengthening of one's own country. A favourable balance of

CONCLUSION

'For a discussion of the dual stnicture of the Otoman economic tradition: Bruce Masters (1988). The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East, NYU Press, NY: 188-201.

^Bruce Masters (1988): 189,

Ibid.

7

Page 85: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

trade was to serve this end,^ Mercantilist policies therefore necessitated abstaining from

imports and encouraging exports. Gold and silver accumulation would result from this

trade policy, which would provide relative strength to the country. On the contrary,

Ottoman economic interests were not protected by similar means on the policy level.

Ottomans were more concerned with "provisionalism". In other words, imports were not

'undesirable' in so far as they provided an environment of "plenty" for the well-being of

the re'aya. Islamic ideal of justice would thus be premised on a market of plentiful and

cheap commodities. It seems that it did not matter whether they were imported or

produced at home as long as local producers were not seriously damaged by them.

Ottomans thus granted the capitulations, whole-heartedly.^

Commodities of provisioning for the needy population, who were "entrusted to

the safe keeping of the lawflil Sultan" differed in priority. Grain, or wheat for bread

production had the first place in this ranking. Istanbul was the primary destination of

wheat supplies. The aim of the Ottoman State was to provide grain for the Istanbul

market, at moderate prices.’ The cultivated land of the Empire belonged to the state.

Together with miff lands, the çift-hane system was to provide a continuous grain

supply.* While the Ottoman State applied strict measures of control over the grain trade,

keeping local production and deliveries at a constant rate; responsibility of offering

reasonable prices for local producers constituted a ground of relative flexibility

A pragmatic motivation seems to have shaped the grain policy, which was not a

particularity of the Ottoman era. As put forward by Rhoads Murphey: "Providing an

'•ibid; 191.

^Eli F. Heckscher (1935). Mercantilism, trans. M Shapiro, I-ll, London. ^İnalcık (1994) ed. with Quataert: 51-52,

’ibid: 185.

76

Page 86: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

adequate supply of grain at affordable prices has concerned all governments in all ages

and all cultural traditions. In the Graeco-Roman World, when there were no developed

networks or institutions of food supplies, people were more vulnerable to food crises that

took place within a spectrum from shortage to famine. Still, in important cities as Athens

and Rome, profits of traders, millers or bakers were regulated. Centuries later, during

the grain crisis of 1917 in Russia, similar measures such as setting up a grain monopoly

were foreseen to solve the problem, " it may thus be appropriate to state that Ottoman

State had a universal scope in its intervention in the grain trade when bread o f the re ‘aya

was concerned.

Bread had an additional symbolic value separate from its exchange value. It was

"the staff of life", for it was the "primary symbol of nourishment".'^ Christianity has a

literature on the value of bread in which bread, wine and oil are three sacred foods

symbolising the miracle of the Eucharist. Jesus Christ himself constituted the essence of

bread, whose creation was metaphorically parallel to the making o f bread.'’ The

traditional image of an average Frenchman was someone with a beret on his head,

carrying a litre of red wine in a bag, and with a baguette stuck under his arm.'“* Muslim

respect for bread and perception of bread as a sacred food is apparent in the name given

to it: nan-1 ‘aziz. In the Ottoman era, bread production, apart from the regulatory

*Ibid.

^Murphey (1988): 217.

lOpgfgj. Gamsey (1988). Famine and Food in the Graeco-Roman World, Responses to R isk and Crisis. Cambridge Universit>· Press. Cambridge: 271-277.

"Lars T. Lih (1990). B read and Authority in Russia 1914-1921, Universitj· of California Press, Berkeley: 58-60.

'^Toussainl-Samat (1987/1992): 230.

'^MassimaMontanari(1994): 15-17.

1(-

Page 87: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

mechanism over grain supplies, was completed within the framework of two significant

practices or institutions: the monopoly of bread production (gedik) and the rules o f the

Islamic market-regulatoiy mechanism (ihtisab). Gedik was the license to produce a good

of state monopoly. The primary condition for holding a license of bread-making was

being a qualified master. Masters were additionally to have flour stocks, to bake bread of

proper quality and weight, and to make their payments in return for flour, on time. State

had a system of records to follow the masters with the trade license. Masters'

replacement, expulsion, or granting a new license was made only after carefial scrutiny o f

the views of the elders of the trade, and often by a court annoncement. Bread monopoly

with its exclusive quality was preserved even in the second half of the nineteenth century,

when all monopolies were abolished. The ihtisab regulation comprised the ethical market

rules imposed by the religious orders of id 'Amr bi’l Ma ruf wa’n-nahy ‘an i’l-Munkar

meaning "ordering good and prohibiting evil". The government official who was

responsible to inspect and practice ihtisab rules was the muhtesib. The price, quality, and

the weight of "sacred bread" fell in the sphere of activity controlled by the muhtesib. The

hisba rules and their implementation was another area of survival of Ottoman institutions

Production of bread was an artisanal activity. At the beginning of this study,

different approaches to the Ottoman guilds' level of autonomy have been mentioned. At

this point, it may be asserted that Ottoman State intervened in the bread-making process

with a motivation that did not decrease at any period in the Empire's entire life. However,

this intervention was not merely shaped by an interest in the artisanal activity-the

functioning of the bakers'guild. Bread was a product of the bakers in the last resort, but

its story was not at all limited by urban production. Looking at the attitude of the

Ottoman state towards this detailed project, it can be said that the state enabled

14.Toussaint-Samat (1987/1992): 239.

77

Page 88: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

continuous bread provisioning with every eflfort. The provisioning project and the

producers of basic necessities is probably an improper sphere of scrutiny o f the autonomy

question. Universally, bread has been subject to strict intervention of governments at all

times.

18

Page 89: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Pamphlet o f Tatarcık Abdullah Efendi

(Tarih-i Osmani Encümeni mecmuası No: 44)

"The residents of wide areas of the capital of the Ottoman State are under the protection

of the reflection of the great Sultan's justice which is immune fi-om oppression. Since the

center o f sultanate is qualified as "the magnet of hearts" (mıknâtîsüT-kulüb), everyone

near the capital are naturally willing to bring their foodstuffs as well as other

commodities (to Istanbul). Since Istanbul is full of blessings of all sorts, its residents are

accustomed to comfort and ease by the variety and plenty of these goods. The justice of

the sultan upon people elsewhere is considered to be as appropriate and fitting, however,

governors, rulers, notables and oppressors do not abstain from causing harm and

injustice to the population. As a result of this situation, the gate(court, residence) o f the

lawful sultan has become the shelter of slaves (kuls) Each time people fi-om other places

come to Istanbul in order to lodge their complaints, or for some other business, they see

and inspect the plenty, luxury, safety, comfort and order in the city. Thus, they become

eager to leave their fatherland and move in Istanbul As an excessive number of people

are accumulated at the capital, migration from other places to reside in Istanbul has been

forbidden. Especially, day-laborers and porters residing at khann rooms and at dükkan

(stores), were sent back to their homes. According to the public security rules, it has

been a regular practice of the past to isolate the capital from the gathering of people.

Special attention and continuous efforts of the public officers and state emins are well-

known. As mentioned above, upon causes and circumstances that have occurred by the

changes that took place throughout centuries, in all Anatolian lands and Mediterranean

islands, governors, rulers, other public officers and tax collectors; particularly the local

notables and despots who molest the people, have caused oppressions that have

exceeded the bounds. Since safety and comfort have been removed and lost in most of

these (Ottoman) lands, troubled people, as a natural humane response, have been

hopelessly compelled to leave their fatherland. These people have whole-heartedly and

with all their force, gathered at the capital, which they considered a safe place to live in.

As previously written, from the icmal, the state is obliged to provide the necessary

amount of goods (for the population). Various difficulties are involved with the

collection of grain for the capital. Obviously, there are troubles o f gathering sufficient

APPENDIX I

79

Page 90: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

grain to meet the subsistence needs of the increased population of Istanbul. Most

important o f all is the provision of a sufficient amount of nan-i ‘azız (sacred bread). The

grain collected from Black- Sea coasts and other places, without exertion of pressure, no

longer suffices to meet the requirements of the population of Istanbul. It is known that,

subsistence and payment of taxes of the people living in the Mediterranean coasts are

conditioned upon their sale of crops to licensed (with permission) foreigners, at higher

prices. It is certain that they will not, by their free will, bring their grain to sell in

Istanbul. For this reason it has been ordered to purchase five to six hundred thousand

keyls of wheat and barley from the Mediten anean coasts at the valid price of that area.

The remainder crop has been allowed to be sold, according to past practices, to the

foreigners. Near the tersane at the capital, miri (state-owned) granaries have been

constructed. Special emfns (requisiton agents) have been appointed to buy (grain) at the

current price. These requisition officers were buying the officially determined amount

according to law, without causing any harm (injustice) and giving the amount completely

to its owners. In time, at the purchasing lu eas, with exceeding prices, plenty of benefits

began to accrue to high offices. Some avaricious and cruel people acquired the

requisition office (mübâya’acıhk) through bribery. They completely left the principle of

equity as they took these offices and exceeding the border of moderation, they put the

re’âyâ into dramatically difficult situations. It became necessary to put forward

continuous efforts to prevent miibaya’acis and other grain officers' acts contrary to

divine justice and the sultanic orders. They had to be content by a share of only one keyl

out o f ten keyls of grain. From then on, honest and generous officers were appointed

without bribery and with modest gifts. They were required to give the officially-

determined amount, completely, to the re’aya. The ones whose oppression and cruelty

was observed would be punished. Thiough official search, acts and deeds were carefully

investigated. Since the people have become happy and content, and since there has been

a significant reduction in the oppression related to the income of grain to the capital, the

path of justice has been found. Since producers were not accustomed to the taking of

grains, by necessity, it is certain that in such cases, they will be offended. Especially, as

the foreigners near the Mediterranean islands are ready to pay cash of two to three

guruş, for every keyl o f wheat, if producers are ordered to take their crop to Istanbul in

times of trouble, no doubt, they will not voluntarily sell their grain at 40-50 para. Thus,

for the ones concerned and çiftliks, the cost of each keyl of wheat will reach 55-60 para

8C

Page 91: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

including çiftçi, orakçı, ırgat wages and other expenses (25-30 para) plus the

transportation cost of shipment and carriage. Under these circumstances, they would

obviously not be able to acquire any profit, moreover, they would be at loss. These

people would not take their crops to Istanbul, by their free will. In case they would be

forced to do so, they would altogether give up agriculture. The price of sacred bread

depends on the cost of wheat. The Black-Sea wheat costs 30-40 para / keyl. The bakers

are willing to buy the Mediterranean wheat at 40 para/keyl, however, high quality

Mediterranean wheat cannot be sold at the at the same price. Thus, Mediterranean wheat

is sold at 50-60 para/keyl. This is a valid excuse for the bakers. They immediately act as

if they have bought all the gram (be it Mediterranean or Black Sea wheat), at the higher

price. By way of adulteration, they pressurize the authority so that they are allowed to

reduce the weight o f nan-i a‘ziz and increase the price of nan-i ‘aceze. The grain o f nan-

1 ‘aztz is prior to every type of grain. Using newly invented practices, re’aya, all the

concerned, and the çifliks are being damaged "

Page 92: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Religious Regulation o f the Ihtisab Practice

The religious aspect of this issue, as listed among the religious duties of the

muhtesib, was ideally concerning the achievement of peace and order in the society. In

Ottoman towns, the mahalle was a unit o f settlement which was built around a mosque, a

church or a synagogue.'^ The people living in the mahalle were responsible to maintain

order, to pay taxes and to carry out all the obligations to the state, collectively.

Although Muslim and non-Muslim artisans and merchants were subject to the same

regulations concerning economic issues, certain restrictions were imposed on the non-

Muslims in eveiyday life. These restrictions are reflected in the clothing regulation in our

d o c u m e n t . T h e document reflects this type of discrimination in the colors that are

considered suitable only for the Muslims. Concerning the development of such

distinctions, Suraiya Faroqhi has asserted that beginning with the eighteenth Century, a

considerable number of artisans had joined the military units-the janissary corps. Through

this allowance, military units turned into paramilitary ones, which led to the blurring of

the distinction between tax paying population and the tax-free military class. According

to Faroqhi, this blurring of boundaries led to the emphasis of another boundary: between

Muslims and non-Muslims.'* A reflection of this empasis is the term rc'aya indicating only

non-Muslims, as in our document. Another possible motivation behind such a

APPENDIX II

İnalcık, "İstanbul," EI2\ 229.

'®Ibid: 234.

‘■'ACRno: 228-123.

'^Suraiya Faroqhi (1995) "Ottoman Guilds in the late EighteenthCentury: The Bursa Analecta Isisiana XVJll, M aking a Living in the Ottoman Lands 1480 to 1820, The Isis Press, İstanbul: 96.

R'

Page 93: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

discriminatoiy motivation may be illuminated by considering the European commercial

connections of non-Muslims that could have created reaction among the bureaucracy.

The other aspect among the religious regulations is the ihtisab tax charged from

the marriages of the re'aya. This is an area that enables us to determine the status groups

of the non-Muslim couples. It is revealed in the document that the status is determined by

the cizye ( A. djizya) paper of the aforementioned couples. Cizye is the shar‘i head tax.

It has been put forward by Halil İnalcık that cizye was fixed considering the wealth and

living conditions of the taxpayer. Parallell to the practice concerning the determination

of ispençe, {ra ’iyyet rüsüınü) the religious tax is fixed at three consecutive proportions

with respect to the status gruops: a ’la. evsat and edna. The proper execution of

compulsory worship-prayers and fasting by the Muslims are regulated by the same rules.

The control over religious life is thus among the duties of the muhtesib who is, therefore,

"ideally" a diyânetkâr and kârgüzar person

'^Suraiya Faroqhi (1995): 96.

"°Halil İnalcık ( 1959)" Osmanlilarda Ra'iyyet Rüsumu," Belleten, XXIII; 61.

83

Page 94: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

GLOSSARY

anadolu Ustası: head of bakers in the Ала1оНап region of Istanbul,

anbar-i âmire: Imperial granary.

çaşni dutmak: tasting bread by officials, to inspect its quality.

çardak: division o f the flour market, where the kapan na’ibi was seated.

dest-ğâh. work-bench; counter,

etm ekci (ekmekçi): bread-maker.

dirbem: a weight o f 1/400 of one okka.

francala: fine, white bread.

fm nci: baker.

gedik: licence to practice a certain trade or craft

babbaz: bread-maker.

bâs-Bâo: pure, white bread.

iaşe amirliği: administration of food supplies.

ibadullab: "servants of God; men"- the population of the empire, in need of the

protection o f the sultan.

icare: rent.

ibtisab: moral laws of guilds and markets,

iskemle: a stool of bread sale with a gedik attached to its position,

İstanbul ustası: head of bakers in Istanbul proper.

карав bacısı: merchant of the flour market.

карав n â ’ibi: the judge o f the unkapani in charge of solving business disputes and

inspecting rules o f provisioning.

koltukcu: salesman without licence, illegal sales-person.

ÖA

Page 95: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

küfeci: mobile salesman of a commodity, with a basket on his back.

kürek: hard labor; penal servitude.

mûbâya ‘acı: requisition agent.

matbah-i âmire: imperial kitchens.

mubtesib: official responsible for the implementation of ihtisab regulations in an

Ottoman town.

nan-t ‘aziz: daily bread percieved as something sacred.

BâD-ı aceze: bread of lower weight compared to "nan-i 'aziz".

nizâm ustası: selected craftsmen and flour dealers who inspected the rules of business in

the unkapani.

okka: a weight o f400 dirhems, or 2.8 lb. (vukiyye)

okkalık francala: fíne white bread with a weight o f one okka.

re ’is: captain of a vessel.

r e ’isler kethüdası: head of vessel captains.

sefine: a vessel.

simidci: baker of a roll of bread in the shape of a ring.

tablakâr: itinerant peddler of goods who carries them on a circular tray on his head

uncu: flour dealer.

unkapani: the flour market.

zâbit: officer of public security.

8S

Page 96: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Primary Sources

Archival Materials

MD Vol: 40, No: 451,461.

MD Vol: 43, No: 101, 164, 197, 277,

MD Vol: 61, No: 9-4.

MD Vol: 69, No: 3-2, 467-235, 523-362, 543-373.

CB No: 428; 548; 878, 1028, 2715; 2938; 3531; 4103; 4567; 5035; 5219, 5236.

ACRVol: III, No: 532; 852.

ACR Vol: IV, No: 266, 356, 385, 4 5 1.

ACRVol: V,No: 1024.

ACRVol: VII, No: 1956.

ACR Vol: VIII, No. 1633, 1634; 2441; 2988, 3069.

ACRVol. IX, No: 1315, 1322; 1323, 1443.

ACRVol: 228, No: 123.

BCR Vol: 161, No: 64.

iCR Vol: 51.

DHED İnalcık Collection No: 8.

DHBD Published by Osman Nuri Ergin, Mecelle: 787.

DHİDNo. 17, 18, 142.

DHMDNo: 111.

Published Primary Sources

Sidki. Gedikler. Dersaadet, 1325,

Osmm'HnnExgm. M ecelle-i Umur-i Belediye. Istanbul, 1337.

86

Page 97: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Secondary Sources

Abdülaziz Bey. OsmanliAdet, Merasim ve Tabirleri. İstanbul. Tarih Vakfı Yurt Yayınlan, 1995.

Abou-El-Haj, Rifa’at ‘Ali. Formation o f the Modern State: the Ottoman EmpireSixteenth to Eighteenth Centuries. Albany, State University of New York Press 1991.

Açıkgöz, Nihat. “Edebi Metinlere Göre 15. Ve 16. Asırda Bazı Osmanh Esnaf Tipleri,” Fırat Üniversitesi Sosyal Bilimler Dergisi 6:1 -2 (1994). 1 -23

Akgündüz, Ahmet. “Ebussud’un Gedik Hakkı ile Alakalı Mühim Bir Risalesi,”, in Osmanh Kanunnameleri ve Hukuki Tahlilleri Vol IV. edited by. Ahmet Akgündüz, 105-121. İstanbul: 1992.

Akarlı, Engin. "Gedik," İVissenschafEkolleg Jahrbuch 19. (1985-1986), 225-231.

Amin, Samir. Avrupa Merkezcilik. Bir İdeolojinin Eleıştirisi. translated by. Mehmet Sert. İstanbul. Ayrıntı Yayınları, 1993.

Baer, Gabriel. “The Administrative, Economic and Social Functions o f Turkish Guilds,” International Journal o f Middle Eastern Studies. 1:1(1970), 28-50.

‘Guilds in Middle Eastern History,” in Studies in the Economic Hi.story o fthe Middle East: From the Rise o f İslam to the Present Day. edited by. M. A. Cook. 11-30 London: Oxford University Press, 1970.

Balta, Evangelia “The Bread in Greek Lands During the Ottoman KwXq,” AnkaraÜniversitesi DU Tarih ve Coğrafya Fakültesi Tarih Araştırmaları Dergisi, 16:27. (1994), 199-226.

Braudel, Fernand. The Wheels o f Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism 15th-18th Century. Vol II. translated by. Sian Reynolds. New York. Harper & Row, 1979/1982.

Buckley, R.P. “The Muhtasib,” ra/>/ca. 39 (1992), 59-117.

Camporesi, Piero. Bread o f Dreams Food and Fantasy in Early Modern Europe. Translated by David Gentilcore Chicago: University o f Chicago Press, (1980/1996).

Çadırcı, Musa. Tanzimat Döneminde Anadolu Kentleri'nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik Yapıları. Ankara: Türk Tarih Kurumu Yayınları, 1991.

Çızakca, Murat. “Price History and the Bursa Silk Industry. A Study in OttomanIndustrial Decline, 1550-1650,” in The Ottoman Empire and the World Economy,

87

Page 98: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

edited by Huricihan İnan-İslamoğlu. 247-261.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.

Dumont, Paul and François Georgeon. Modernleşme Sürecinde Osmanli Kentleri. Tarih Vakfı Yurt Yayınları, 1996.

Ergenç, Özer. “Some Notes on the Administration Units of the Ottoman Empire,” ICUIT, Session 11, 1989, 426-441.

___________ . OsmanlI Klasik Dönemi Tarihçiliğine Katkı: XVI: Yüzyılda Ankara veKonya. Ankara: Ankara Enstitüsü Vakfı Yayınlan, 1995,

Faroqhi, Suraiya. New Perspectives on Turkey. 5-6 ( Fall 1991), 1-27.

______________. "Fieldglass and the Magnifying Lens: Studies o f Ottoman Crafts andCraftsmen," JEEH.

‘Introduction,” New Approaches to State and Peasant in OttomanHistory, 1992, 3-18.

______OsmanlI ’da Kentler ve Kentliler. İstanbul: Tarih Vakfi Yurt Yayınları,1993.

. “Ottoman Guilds in the I .ate Eighteenth Century The Bursa Case,” inAnalecta I si si ana X llII, Making a Living in the Ottoman Lands 1480 to 1820, 93-112. Istanbul: Isis Press, 1995.

________, Osmanh Kültürü ve Gündelik Yaşam. Translated by Elif Kılıç. İstanbul:Tarih Vakfı Yurt Yayınları, (1995/1997).

French, David. A Sixteenth Century Merchant in Ankara. United Kingdom, 1972.

Garnsey, Peter. Famine and Food Supply in the Graeco-Roman World: Responses to Risk and Cri.sis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.

Genç, Mehmet. “Osmanli Mâliyesinde Malikane Sistemi,” in Türkiye İktisat Tarihi Semineri, Metinler Tartışmalar, edited by. Osman Okyar and Ünal Nalbantoğlu.231-296. Ankara: 8-10 Haziran, 1973,

Gerber, Haim. State, Society and Law in Islam: Ottoman Law in Comparative Perspective. New York. University of New York Press, 1994.

Hall, John A. “In Search of Civil Society.” in Civil Society, Theory, History,Comparison, edited by. John A. Hall. United Kingdom: Polity Press, 1995.

İnalcık, Halil (1947). “Bursa Şer’iyye Sicillerinde Fatih Sultan Mehmed’in Fermanlari,”jff, XI, 693-708.

88

Page 99: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

_________ . “OsmanlI İmparatorluğu’nun Kuruluş ve İnkişafi Devrinde Türkiye’ninİktisadi Vaziyeti Üzerinde Bir Tetkik M ü n ase b e tiy le ,X V , 1951, 629-690.

_________ . “ 15. Asır İktisadi ve İçtimai Tarihi Kaynaklan,” İFM, XV, (1953-54)51-57.

. “OsmanlI Hukukuna Giriş,”5'5FA XIII, 1958, 102-126.

. “OsmanlIlarda Raiyyet Rüsumu,” 5 , XXIII, 1959, 575-610.

. “Bursa and the Commerce of the Levant,” 3, 1960,131-147.

“The Rise of Ottoman Historiography,” Historians o f the MiddleEast, eds. B. Lewis and P. Holt, London, 1962, 152-167.

__________ . " O d fiA , IX, 1964, 672-683.

“Yükseliş Devrinde Osmanh Ekonomisine Umumi Bir Bakış,” TK, 68,1969, 537-541

__ . “Capital Formation in the Ottoman Empire,”7717/, XXIX-1, 1969, 97-140.

. “The Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects o f the Ottoman Economy,” ifJ the Economic History o f the Middle East, ed. M. A. Cook, London: Oxford University Press, 1970, 207-218.

__________ “Istanbul,” ¿72, IV, 1973,224-248.

. “Osmanh İmparatorluğunda Kültür ve Teşkilat,” Türk Dünyası ElAnkara: TKAE, 1976, 974-990.

_____________ “Centralization and Decentralization in Ottoman Administration,”Studies inEighteenth Century Islamic History, eds. T. Naff and R. Owen, London, 11- 52.

. "The Hub of the City. The Bedestan of İstanbul,” UTS, I/l, (1979-1980), 1-17

'Military and Fiscal Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 1600-MOOfAO, VI, 1980, 283-337.

Osmanli Pamuklu Pazarı, Hindistan ve İngiltere: Pazar RekabetindeEmek Maliyetinin Rolü,”G/9, Özel Sayı II, (1979-1980). “1-65

. “Introduction to Ottoman Metrology,” T, XV, 1983, 311-34.

89

Page 100: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

“Yük (Himi) in Ottoman Silk Trade, Mining and Agriculture,” T,XVI, 1984, 131-156.

__________ . “İstanbul: An Islamic City Journal o f Islamic Studies, 1990, 1-23.

_______________ The Appointment Procedure of a Guild Warden (Ketkhuda)," TheMiddle East and the Balkans Under the Ottoman Empire: Essays on Economy and Society, Indiana, (1986/1993), 194-201.

_______________ , Ottpman Empire the Classical Age. London: Phoenix, (1973/1994).

_________ . An Economic and Social History o f the Ottoman Empire: 1300-1914.edited by Halil İnalcık with Donald Quataert. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.

Heckscher, Eli. Mercantilism, translated by M. Shapiro, London: 1935.

Ibn Taymiya. Public Duties in Islam. The Institution o f Hisba, Translated by Muhtar Holand, UK: The Islami Foundation, (1402 A H. /1982).

İnan-İslamoğlu, Huricihan. Osmanli İmparatorluğu 'nda Devlet ve Köylü. (State andPeasantry in the Ottoman Empire), translated by. Sabri Tekay. Istanbul: İletişim Yayınlan, 1991.

İslamoğlu Huricihan and Çağlar Keyder. “Agenda for Ottoman History,” Review 1:1 (Summer 1977), 31-55.

Kaplan, Steven Laurence. The Bakers o f Paris and the Bread Question: 1700-1775. Durham: Duke University Press, 1996.

Kütükoğlu, Mübahat. Osmanlı-îngiliz İktisadi Münasebetleri. Ankara: Türk Kültürünü Araştırma Enstitüsü, 1974.

__. OsmanlIlarda Narh Müessesesi ve 1640 Tarihli Narh Defteri.İstanbul. Enderun Kitabevi, 1983.

Le GofF, Jacques. 'The Medieval World, translated by. Lydia G. Cochrane. India: Collins& Brown, 1990.

Mantran, Robert. 17. Yüzyılın İkinci Yarısında Istanbul: Kurumsal, İktisadi, Toplumsal Tarih Denemesi. Vol. I-II. Translated by Mehmet Ali Kıhçbay and Enver Özcan. Ankara: Türk Tarih Kurumu, 1990.

Montanari, Massimo. The Culture o f Food. Translated by Carl ipsen, The Making of Europe Series, Cambridge: Blackwell, 1994.

____________ .XV. Ve XVII. Yüzyılda İstanbul’da Gündelik Hayatı, translated by.Mehmet Ali Kıhçbay. İstanbul: Eren Yayınları, 1991.

90

Page 101: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Mukninova, R.G.“ Craftsmen and Guild Life in Samaraqand,” in Timurki Art and Culture: Iran and Central Asia in the Fifteenth Century, edited by Lisa Golombek and Maria Subtelny. 29-34, Leiden. E J Brill, 1992.

Murphy, Rhoads. “Provisioning Istanbul: The State and Subsistance in the Early Modern Middle East.” Food and Foodways. 2; (1988), 217-263.

Omar, Farouk. “Guilds in Islamic City During the Abbasid Period (749-1258 A.D.).”’ ICUIT, Session 12, 1989, 197-217.

Pandey, Gyanendra. “The Colonial Dislocation: Muslim Weavers and Their Industry in Colonial North India.” ICUIT, Session 9.370-423,

Raymond, André. Osmanli Döneminde Arap Kentleri. Istanbul: Tarih Vakfı Yurt Yayınları, 1995,

Reynolds, Susan Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe 900-1300. Suffolk: St. Edmundsbury Press, 1992,

Salzmann, Ariel, “An Ancien Régime Revisited: ‘Privatisation’ and Political Economy in the Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Empire.” Po//7/c.s· & Society. 21:4 (December 1993), 393-423,

Taeschner, Franz, “Islamda Fütüwet Teşkilatının Doğuşu Meselesi ve Tarihi Ana Çizgileri,” translated by. Semahat Yüksel. Belleten. 12, 6-49.

Tamari, Salim. “Shopkeepers, Peddlers and Urban Resistance in the Palestine Uprising ” \CUIT, Session 12, 1989, 170-203.

Tarih İçinde Muğla, edited by. İlhan Tekeli, Ankara: Metu Faculty of Architecture Publication, 1993,

The Ottoman Empire and the World-Economy, edited by. Huri İslamoğlu-İnan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987.

Togan, isenbike. “Karşılaştırmalı Tarih Penceresinden: Moğollarla İlgili Çalışmaların Türklerin Tarihi Açısından Düşündürdükleri.” Unesco Milli Komisyonu İnsan Bilimleri İhtisas Komitesi Tarih Yazıcılığı Sempozyumu. Ankara, 9-10 March 1995.

Uluçay, Çağatay. XVİİ. inci Yüzyılda Manisa 'da Ziraat, Ticaret, ve Esnaf Teşkilatı. İstanbul: C.H.P. Manisa Halkevi Yayınları, 1942.

_. 18 ve 19. Yüzyıllarda Saruhan 'da Eşkiyalık ve Halk Hareketleri.İstanbul: 1955.

91

Page 102: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

J" ^ W J V / - ( l r · . . ;

■ JjJ

'4 ./і > ; 5 ; ' : ^ , ' 4 і Л . / . , .

л / / і ' ' '

% Г , j ' \ J

■!f 'Щ г ~ ^ 0 , } У і-' Ğ h ^ J , JJ* J f>* *)

. f /

CEVi> ET 6 ecEû ( Y E ■. А-ХЯ

Page 103: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

, ■ ■ ■■

. \ \ \ . . l ^ j ' ( V * I

c ^ j \ ^

''У'·' *'■'

1 Ч Κ·> »►,t/i

. Æ. ,'i ;

■ > . .. .... i .Í», ,"; .;.ι·,..,···ί .Λ· ί i V ■»·„ '

■ Ш е:У ■

Page 104: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

• КУ'У

• Λ- ί■ЧΛ «• νϊ4'•■Ц

ί'"i*' t•'=ΐχ.Λ ' Λ·■V‘ ^ ο45>

' ·■ ■'3·

- 'Λ'Я •4·'І i•χ1

■ ·4 ·

Ск

- Λ

4

;:. ■ Ш

Page 105: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Λ '

' 9 ' ·

á -

^ ·

1 I СЛ .

V ·

Λ

Page 106: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

л- ΐ 3 ? J S i ' · ϊ ·ΐ· ·ί" ? ^ ' W ^ - - ^ ■ ^-'■ ^ ''· ^ ν''· ^

4 ^ 4 > ' ί · · ) - ?' ^ ·

J

■ _Ό' -^3 ъ - ' < ^ · \ ν ν . ^ ι : ' J - - ν ^ V -->

' ^ > д " ί ■? ^ · 'V - Á ^ ' Д -я" V· ; > X д -Г’ V , - ^ · ■ ■ ^ • л - ; д J ' Í д

j i - f í 3 4 ; Ϊ , ί , ” 4 ' - ? · л

• Д ' - Л ; з А ; Д л Д А Д \ ѵ ■ Ч '· ' ^ ' ^

О ÿ ■'J Λ '^ V ·^ л ѵ

Д A ' AA Ч r ,

A \ Í -%.1-9^ ^ Л І ІЛ " \ ^ S ' Ά ' - χ · ■ « Л Α · чѴ ‘ - А · Ч \ з - . д ■ V - з - ^ . ѵ ^ ' Ь X • b w ' ' '

• V ' J í T ^ V Д ^ ^ Д . Д - Д · Í ■. , - ÿ ■ А - î - Í ? Д , '

V 3 Л -3. 3 . 3 . 3 з ;

і Ч | л t і^ - з ' Л

-_so

V л

A i ѵ . 3

А Г і ? ' ν ' ->■ д V ^•х' ·\· І' τ'· 3 Д Д 1 А ) 3 -3 '-Ф

4 ^ - - ч 4 - і д · . ? ■') ■ ' V 4 3

■^ ■ 4 4 ' Í · ? ' з ί* 3 ^ ' t ^ д д ’ ^•ΐ,· - Д - І . V 4 . V ^ ' О V ^ ѵ · \ : 4 -■> • ^ '

л - , 0 3 3 - Í à X А А А 4 ' · Ά - V S Д

Ά i а ; . а I л З І ч > і - , С

Д Λ •^■' ' J · · Ζ Д ' "-' , Α . ^ · Д ^ ^ " ¿Ι Τ ^ ^ ^ Λ ' Ş 'Д 3 \ v ' í ‘ ^ ' ' ‘д -' ц ^

Д 3 Д ό ' ν . · · ' ^ · 4 . ѵ л ч \ Ѵ · ê

Page 107: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

д J· : · .f ? Д- 3--И' Î ä ^^ ^ ? i» . ^ Г ’ ^ ^ л'' , ' i .< 0 ^ :î

C ' q ?■ ->' ' - i A ? » - -» · ^ S ' V - ? Д

V - Í ? i ^ :s> · ? · .■ # ' S ' . - i

^ . . . r S i > ^ · V « , - » ^ Ù ' · ? ί . : νΛ.? ?’Л

. ' j o ï } S 3 ,ν \ . ■ о\ Ъ '

■ - .· ' · ί ■■ ' ' ¿ ’ · V . ■' ο ’" ΐ '•“' ί ί ■^^ · . ^ ·

^ ' І л ^ .? s ' ? * ε · ' i \ . ~ 0 .1 Д ■> ■ .? ' < ' - 4^ ' , - ν - . | , ÿ . γ . Д · , \ J ,-Λ г r f - · ) · , ^ . > J ·

- V * jJ · Λ Л ; ÿ - ^ ' \ Α * ν

ѵ А - Ч - ' ^ · '■' ν ' - ί - η ’' Λ ·^ ■ Э ' Ч - t " - ^- X ί Д J . :.Ş> _ ί ί · Д - % 1 л Ѵ ^ Д ^Д Д : ѵ;д γ :§ V. νφ J,·' J ·4

^ s > = 4 ^ ν . ΐ . ^ -> Л - Н V ·<Γ V4 ^ · ^ - ^ ' · 4 " ' ^ Α ί ' 7 - Ν· i s ' ' : ' ^ . 5 \ . г , г : ^ д

'S

^ 1 . 4 ;#^ - Д

\ J-- ·.r

*\ V N * ЛЛ' ^ ;ѵ.

МШ ’

Page 108: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

( '

Ѵ Л .rf '«Γ

r - ‘‘

'Ч 'Ф' ■-

I -vrr'.-’x·> ;

' -

t -Ч'

. ,^'·,JI.,». .W-Î^ '

'ч„ 'К ' ’-

VЧ‘г V.

ö 'i

-S-Ü 'A '^Îİa ¿, , U ^ д , , . и

Page 109: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

■ Í o : - Л

Page 110: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

/Т '\ ·' ■ ;

J

b ' ,

· Κ

• t ' г ь ' '-■ ί ϋС -ê ί· ■>. F■ P Λ '. ί · r Vt P. Λ г ‘

.' V.: ^ ^ rÍ Л · 'Â . f t :

•У Λ (5 F ■

i · f ^ '

, . . . . .'f' l ' b

i i i'I 'Vif r . ' l '·

e - tv t

i '· Ê 4, f ' . y ·β y Ч·

ï - I Í · . ï ' r

V *'· ' t ► ^ f -

& t i . ■■' , i '

f ÿ я ï .Jîi:r .

eU

ç·, Ы - · - I

: t . Э f . f · Kл^ - f t ■ .A

Page 111: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

^ \ y j i \ oX^ c jjj ¿u >» O í *A> 0 ъ о Ъ у і ^ j ) 'i

Λ •^JX: -

Щ . , ( ^ " ‘ ·

Page 112: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Г

иѵ < 4 ^ /

^ I îii^'"’

O X \¡ y ^ [ .¿ jy f* <-

‘ >V:J 4 v' .Í \ - ·-

— V > ^

r—

Page 113: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Г "

(2,ч

/A * û \

0 )é iù > φ } ^ ¿S^))i (^ ] ;^< 1 Х Щ

ξ 0r · ^ w г

ГV

Page 114: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

dzùij)

^ ¿ιέ

/ / ¿у y ^ J i ^ y у ^ Ç } ^ J , J ιχ i

tí: '

rL < /j

¿ t ' 'r I /

íífe íí.®

Page 115: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

J % \ ; «.Si

ç y I (¡/ y j J . I> ^ \ '' j T, i y ^ ^ , Γ ι ' . ^ ^ c

/w"oc<

/il)y 1 ^

¿ . iJ i •^j> f ^ j j i• - r ------ -- '" - '• r

c ^ \ ^ ÿ 6 ^ y M , / ' c J j ^ ^ j f y i <î·»/ • ^ j / : 4 '

^ } *j-f y y ^ ( j^ j^-^yJI іЛ Ь I ^ / / jú S - ^ i/У /У ^ *

-•^j- t Z ^

y ^ J ) r y J i y ^ J y ^ / у У і { } J ^'^1 bùjt^pj.

. S - » y ' o ù T l fr j f (

C A i ' j i f f '¿ z ¡ ^ ¿ ζ - ''Z X Í^ c zy i ^ j Z j I

i Z b S i i y , u , \ ^ c ^ ' j ^ l /

£>/<<: ^*oyj! r ih ^ ^УІуУУ c> ^ ! /—

‘'Z-^y' У ^ ^ '“ у''‘УУі У і У//y , r - · - i ~ - t - ........

iS îM S Â ^ S e a s fe

/1 cR. 3 / "> 3 ίλ

Page 116: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

I J ^ <í>i J^-y¿^ j-α ν ç^ . jÛ ^ tv-ft»

Γ .4 U j J C ^ » o¿ jX ^, e^>jjJ^ ) J / ^ ^ ^ > ¿ · *( i / j_*Xt V >-» /-»

f * J j> l 4 ^ / J ^ 3

^¿)Λ ΐ^/:Λ ί^^ϊ I j ü

7^'·^2 (Л ^ І^ г о '

^У у -»V' <^>% -<^>^<íf i íl»/ ^^ X - t ^ І/ L í- f ¿ ^/ r ^ í o Уу t^y if^J 'f'f ' y f

Λ . . . . . .<í^7>^ ί/>-'ί5

^ у ^ у д а 'б ¿ ¿ ^ / > x /

' i ) 'i j .j’ySTjP

*г ^ /ІУ у і \ j y j \^i^yd) Ç\i y X*

_________ ___ ______

• ■ \M \

f t c i i 3 / 5 5 A

Page 117: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

y.

/

à j^J^^li^y ljf-O 'л ^ Ы ^

^ O J>^

- ¿ y ^ b ^ j j ^ ' i í ¿ y ^ t f ^ l ) , y y с ^ ^ ) У \ j i ^ ß

< < ^ j^^¿ U Í> C Ù ^ ^ ^ J ’ ^y-JU '-;^ y jC ^ ,^ - J - , ,

c ■

И ^ (ii ^ir^^JJ>j Jy>^ /!л— L (J— 0 |^ (Sj^^/i>·^^'kf>y ÖP—» J Lip Ѵ^л'

. s t \ A İ a t \ t· · ^ à · I ** i \ % Ä ··

>>i^)j3 «JÜJ ' IP y>i^ ( / «>Гл->-'J-» I

7 ^ ' ■ ^ ¿ T u

/ >>>4 Ь І Р І J ι> -^ b U > lc -b ¿ ¿ ¿( j

1/V. * % . c r . -» .I-V '' ' . ‘ · *Л»лі J ѵ Л > « Λ · U»

/) с P- ^ 1

Page 118: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

t’i “t Í/! Л i*jy .'Ê T ^

¿ Tл \

' O '

ù‘iA><^ i ■ > 4 ί · > ; ; ώ /

- ^ ■ j y - ^ J f * y . ' y - / . 4 - . - $ V

^ ^ ^ ·' ' · - ' ........... / • ^ - ' • ^ í . r 4 : / y ¿U -y< i2t4 i'

y ^ 2 y ) ù j ) - г ^ ^ - > J -

-j ------- « _-*í >44 '

■yfjjy х Л

^ dií

у6 ^

AcR^ 4 / ’4')'í

Page 119: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

i/^ '/J > t¿ ¿ - ^ - y x - ¿ V ^ o ^ ¿ 0 ; í / > -»' ^ j j y i X i f í C > jJ j/^ '{ ^ X ; Р /, ¿ /

c rfJjr%> /-^Ú ^J í> ij' к $ * *

J liï',' f ó j ^ \ í ¡ j 4w (■!· ¿_¿ly Lv * ' ^ ” ·;-i¿;.yjJfló'c'-C'’->i*A^>^*‘ ^'^'^*cJLtí-'Vji¿','*<><í^¿>/

¿i- j-’C>i* < Jj*Ó>,

A C R

Page 120: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

• - /J J yj: /U J ^ 'J - ‘ ‘

ù j> ^ ' i ' f

O l/^JM ü^j> ç ^ i^M t j ) û -if i o j / ^ -Ί/^Ι) fí¿ ô } 0 i> ^ /yr¿0--> I

( r ) J > y (C f io ^ ß ^ J 0 J>

^ j ^ J £ ^ 1 ^ β y-fiç^j.)

У ^ У у ^ У 4 ^ ^ { / ? ^ ^ - ’ y j>^J А / у у '

ô ^ M y ^ y f · ’ y t y ii-fJ ( r < ^ іл.і, ’ y . . i _____J .: < j / / l , . „ ’ 1 . , . . . !

*^/ / ' · - -' * wy y fi^yifj!^,b b )y ^ 'J rf y J y y y u/iyjyJ f ' ß ^ J y h j ' ^ l y ^ y y b U } У r^ y yrßy*'^

у и у o y y jjy ^ ^ iM - ^ jy .y y■ ' ^ tv^ U ■,

1'-'y 'ß fij^ y ]^ y J *fy¡yjis iJ<3 \<ß<p}o /< о

i f ^ y ß y y y ß j'y ^ · ^ '^ b l г y ÿ^ / ! f k ß y y ÿ y ,^

y \ ( f / y y 'ß y y y y ' jC y ^ У У У ~ * f) : ’У

y jy ^ y A f y ^ y ^ j y j y ^ f ^ f '

i& y ß'' ' jy y/yy^ y y ,■ β γ - j y y y y ( ^ , ^ л / У - ' · - · • • ^ ' ^ ·

(f \ / . ^· ■ '

( \a .ÍL ^ ¡ о У

Page 121: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

I :^ jj¡ I lo (^ j) I ( 1 2p ríí* ¿j¡} é - o ú j ' ^ j ¡ y ¿ ,

^1 ; í , 2 ) J ;

X L - Í¿ > ^ ¿ aj

^ ó i<p Ü Jí

■ Jd-. í l— i VÜj ¿ ^J > J> j!'a íTp

¡ C i 'J j y j i j / í i i j y ' r '. 'V ' - ’ l

rC ifJ^V , . j . ' T " f

^ ^ p j j í ^ іу^ІЛ ¿ a lr t ’ú ^

f\C(L 5 / ι ο λ 4 -

Page 122: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

J l»

' .......’ ' ' j W y J - ^ T ......'’¿ /Щ ^ ^ '~ " ^ ^ ^ > f y,

Ну ІйΛ · л \ . . ^ >,\| . * J \ ' k l* lf îi л^уЧ ^ / і A * H Î I > O f fcíf .Κλ---<Ί Ι % e^· J %

ж щ ш Ж ^ М &

3 χ ΐ _ ^ , , ¿ ^ > ç ^ U y j 2 W <З^Щ'

i^ A À i„ . -r. , . . л і . (’ ^ ’ " ' Ч . , , . ,

s'P ,'èy*)^, ■¡t \'¡ ¿ fi •óC-'*ti'3'¿''í¿xjgL,^_,

АСЯ- ~ ^ 1 { ‘ э(>

Page 123: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

\ . ’ ........-.....................

- * -*....... J \

Α> bl>ji,

- 4 ¿ ' ’’

U 0 > с Ы ^ »Uv ' r ¿y і ' ‘Ѵс'--.«>'ЦcjC./1* /\ rt»_ I·*.(*>.ч·Ч α*.j»r

..... . - 1 . ' ‘Г H . . .( 4^r fiS líXí ' Л.ДУ . . ' ■ I

íi^ü',á*y(u;*^i>'cV^-^'^^'^l'’ ‘4‘vti^A^

ij <'wiv'W í¿· i>) tt·/ tJÍ'«^>¿^.¿'i'¿Uí'<C-;· ‘rV’! С-.Л ·ιί í'ilí.* . . .· . . 1. .».. І.,ч\-Л' .к*

------ -------- -----------------------í> L .f *> yf.’ /"'*'

I ) jK> I>l^i jj> '

■ ^ < ^ ylt^ ^ ^ _ ¿ ¡^ ^ ,^ .....,,.. .A.

• y

- 'i ; t f ! / J < í u . c C f / í , > f j

___ x> \> ¿ríL-_Lvíl ,

Д ---- -t/^ ¿A-<» CÍV'

^ ^ ! ,lyjf^^i;;. <Cí 4>.

^ γ ·· β ^ } ιί^ > .' } ίι^ u'’>UWbá-lfüfjíí'Á' гЗДі^і, 1 <> w Jtítlííí tí^'

■’«í?íí^¿í^ji>^ '>f\'^w¿yívj»:,iiA;j,\l'Í4;íji

yw»44v|i<» •^V»*^í?‘*^VíA«¿elíCtTpíútej í»>^á\t¿itítóp

i>'*y-»> i· «¿*.f¿víy >

ACP^ í’ / i n ^ ' / t ' M

Page 124: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

' ЛзСJS ÍL U i4 ^ b .ÍA .v lj^ J lS j· , M ! ^ ' ' m ,j ^ , ,

‘ и»'Я>^ ^ufCajty '¿Д-'!**/^ U L*ís í l/¿íí^!Xr 'h'> -! ty а Л > i u"í

•OÇyoiSjj.

<¡í - A ^> ,X 'A > j ' ^ J l>*

í ^ —Л л у / р ^ Л ^ р r>'*

r : ^

λ'^'- ^ < Р й Р Ъ г ' 1

ή UL ? ·λ

Page 125: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

>**і#'Ло 'Λ' tM? uf-c · ^ M>^ ' ·

ií5:5í, ц

^ ' " " ' ' ..................

V<^4tÍPVi;·

• í^ W ^ γ''·'?<

^С'^ШЛ'У^^^ ЙЗо^ /Ѵ çl·'

<^(j^yJ^^‘>^.>^ÿ^J^Jo<i^is:-^tf'j»j^ * Vl>,ii <>Чü а \Яу -t í* (ЖУЛЯАІУ « у -Ùj(,l

" ш m * * ·"и:г'

Д С І^ ϋ :^0ЬЗ

Page 126: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

PÍ//H Msliî/ ¿f í w 4 îiû (i-^¿í^->^" ^ \ ¿ ^ ' i l ; i j ^ '¿ly->>-u-->’->V; " *ι^-ί^Λ5θ>

> - ■■^V'-v46»'>¿<vfei>./;^¿v<Jlt^ a^yy>j jM íí r!> 'Í *(f V/ by *>4<>í¿’Ít'^^>> - JÍ Í.>í

üí¿*\ícvé^ ^

■^*í t¿K4}5^¿W> <>y ííl';^

'^ u i <Vx U I^ ¿ f ^ - ^ - o ^ l í - T ^ ^ r T g ^

Ni^Ayt ) 4 ' > w # r f >

Леа. :¿4-4l

Page 127: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

y< * i ^ , . . . . " - 'VJ>

^^MuiPub'f^j¿;^[%fi(^¿j/pyhc'^j>i/ij>^ «ij

”V.· ' ~SÇ^D . ¿-¡j ^ ^¿ oCa* H íi¿' ■ · t^ 4 ¿ í Ç1 X)0^ -Lríi-i-i)' /^"r^>\

—K- TT-r- ,··<_ίΐ'· ' < '/ M bül {/

*^' ■ ......... ' ^ ^

m»V ^ . í ^ - - ^ fe "

ï j ^ ' .

'^//> '>,fÿ«jv , . .

ЛСГ^ 3 / ι 4 · β

Page 128: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

і а і н і

/

f ï» > , .- »^ 1-

à \ ^ · , # · >I 5 , ? ^ ^

-' ’ IS

I

<^

c::¿O

Page 129: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

cevDgr e>euo-ri¿'·

^(J ·^ о UÛİ’ » > Oy (3 '-« 0 \ß ’ о /*yj у '-i ОіД> [tj

liV^'^·^'’' ‘ '.V W Jy} » ',· üi о lÂ-^y С ^ ' У* ОЕ; и*лд ^Sy ОУІ^ ^U>y ( 2 ^ i Ц ' •»ßaj^\>чу'у уул^з ѵі-\ tjy ' оу ' «>>у (ЛУ^уІ'*'.' · ' ‘Ui'>*f· ¿ii.'o>;>ÿ оѴ/ otí>'>>^ r^ í¡P ciJu / a ' ■'

U i v ' ¿ ' ^ r l ^ ' · < \ ^ , / ^ ^ > - » ' ь> (Til''Jî ê.i-V' /“ -*/ .* * . . Г ‘ ' , - . ' * J / ‘. / ,'*" ^jJr L®• ■ 0 ; ^ O J ^ y O jA £> ßj> а>уѴ > b j}'y .ó< (^ ):> JÍ' ' 'У -^ 'у ^ г (у ^ а Х > ‘у 'у^ 1 0 ^ 1 ^ у у у У > * ^ Ь > e ’j · ''^ t y j ^ ) \

z/yy— ' ^)/*P '> сУ ^ (L là-« Ы^,' ^ ^.' ^ Ù* U ^ P 0 u._ ^ , ,*··>“. \ n * " - V \ . ЛІ J 1 /V ¿ . Л. . 1 á\j_-« Lblt ' H_CL> »S ' i i ^ Λ ) > rt · Λ · \ í V/

>';) c>>^ '■ ■ ✓ y j “7 ■ ■ ' » ■ — ~ . » , ”' · r— w g J p p«y l¿ 1.Λ Λ '-JH ^'/n , .L¿J w ^ti><);^>^lk 4 ^ j'' jS>y> ЛІи ,’ Ι Ι 4- ,, ■

-i'-fc > | Γ . · * . \ Ι > · . . л * y ä у J y » J t ' t 1 . * - 1 ., 1 * · . . ' ( * . - . i Л_ ' *U Uy O Oy W ^ '-іу у ■ ■ y iγV ^■ '^иуу^' ·^у^у ϋ «l'If ,І4> íy>>y

r . y . ç ; · , (2 \ ^ ^';.L¿.í - cO ^ İA>y у V <İj>j.> J j U · ) ., w"'λ'Ί . / ¿ . ’ ’ *''г'УУу^ У ' U ^ ^\f, L ' Ч-/ и J'J ^ u ^yji Ö

- ü ; ' Ч«1з'и> у^ y U ClJOW 4 ^ r* r o LJ^y c¿ íM j j 'л/ <V¿j>Jy j p ' l, * î ·* i· > ^ ' t^y Л ^ . 4 ^ ®. y f y p * ^ r ^ ' £ \ > - ^ y ' U ı ^ ' aVJ J >U Oy· U^^¿v i>y.>U o > ' « \ д .: .1 , ^

ѵ ^ ^ Д і, C ü ^ ^ yL ^ ^ j> (2:^ y>^.' о>Л^у^Я wv U v>./ ı ^ l> o >ді.^ ' o UJ a ^^7 ·· .- . / · ................ · . . / v â j cjU3 mj¿¿. (^y^y^

Page 130: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

Э · | ? “ 3 > · _·Ν .

г і Л ^ Щ Л - ^ Н г х і

! ' . f l İ M - i î ' U ■■’ ·■'3 ^ Ѵ - ' ^ Л ' -U •''5

\ · ^ ο ·Δ · η Ч ν · ν . ^ ^ -•1- ''V1 - ! ^ • ^ • М · . .

^ * o ' • \ ..

A 'l i

? ^ } · · ί I · | ' η Γ • Í ’ J ·λ

\ Ч ο ' ^ - ^ · ı ^ ^ * Д * и · ~λι ‘ί ’ τ

• Ч - Ѵ л ^ • ' J . 1 J ^ \ : с . Ч : - ^ .. - ' ^ • 'ΐ \ Λ J ' ^ ^ \ ·

3 λ· ν ^ λ , γ . · \ ? ; . ^ V 4 1 Ϊ '

7. 3 · ' " ^^ ί· ■ ^ 'Λϋ . - ' Λ Λ> ' ^Λ Λ ·\

’ b ^ Э

*ΝV · ^ *^ . λ' . ^ ' . s

. . 3 :3, ν _ , ν

• Ä

- f s ^4 ^ ί Λ A " ΐ ·3 -*' 3‘ i a *4 Vb о ^ ‘V ^

_ ΐ ’ â “ Λ* · \ ^ ί · А "Ч

I · ” ч ? ' · ί « · 7 . · ι ·' · 3 04J _ « á V . . Ş , ^ · ; 3

à^ · э V 'N

:A

Λ0^ Д O y "D ^ '’S* --

^4 ^ ^ .;v *3s 'b -b ·_ί ‘- ^ ·1 ‘ _4 *Л \

5 ; 3 3 · Ч · ; 7 -J r i J ·)' ^;'$Hilf :vH'· \ - l r ^ O ^ . ’' · $

Page 131: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

C€\j DET B eL -E D Î^ /^ :

*■ *

і-^ і) \ ^ 1 Jub l ¡ > j <-¿jJJ I "’Л ^ 4 m À U l ^ a j A > ^ ' r U ^ I ’ ^ X ) L > i ¿ ^ y j , ¡ S > ^ ] ' ' ^ j > ^ · 4 ^ c v <- J L » y

J O' J)o y U - ' ^ b ^ } y ¿ ' ' i >L^J 1 b C i X ^ y o ^ j y y i ^ j ^ j > y ^ j > ¿ U f <

i i j Û à J b J J J J I ^ / O U ^ j^ J ^ i- * i·-*'-»' t ¿ y ^ ^ ^ и ^ -^ и Е " у Ѵ _ ^-^ДІ-^с-> .’y f ^ dJ^ I L ^ ^ J . I у > ' } E j L > ^ L o ЛУ ил» ^ U ^ ' > ^ U ( J y ^ j ' o ^ y ş j L iJ ^

L )j\j \j>j ^ y oy L “L^/Y. o ^ J л*^у, J>'>^ ’¿b'í^ ’ ' '^ r ^ ^ '' ' 4Л ^-? o и’y)L·^ ápj j ^ J - í< j^ ^ ίΐ»!^^^ <)“3^ ^ (л<* ¿^

!y h ^ L í^ !J ,L y l l^^Lzjy l /J C l L ^ L '>V i y > J r ^ I .Ï o ^ d y _ 4 L j^ y > o ^ I c > -^ ¿ > ü ^ j l f ^ j ) ^ u f d ^ U f I ^ /__

J o ^ i l d U Á ^ I ^ r d ^ ' «->>>>*-> tO'’ ■'' ' h ' ' c j y jj y ÿ y j J " »>J í ^ - > ' 4 ^ t ^ i - »

і ^ У і г > o y } y j y d > ^ 'i> J > ïi ' 'U U ^ d L L L ! U ^ t ^

. ^ ^ (2І,· U ¿ j í iJ i f i C d > k С і ^ у У у L ' y A f ^ υ > ' ^ ^ ( i l . ^ t

\ j 4 p ÿ ς>-*^ c¿>¿» о d d d C d > .i ] /J '■'! ^ y u ^ - < J > J i J j ) j ^( d j ÿ , > ^ ' i ^ j > ^ J 4> 'нг ¿ y d c i l j y d j о L ^ j ' J J ¿ $ У ^ f ( J ‘ l y L o > *Z>.> ç _ y ^ a y j \ / y dJ-âj J j jd ^ I ' J 9 /I L j ^ ^y^S' І л ' L/ y f L f c J ¿ A jy .~ o ¿> / } j j y { ‘. î j , ^

^ i y y y j b . > b ^ / d ^ ¿ d h ' ' ? L b \ ^ ‘у А ^ o . > U \ ^ ( J . ^ o ' y f À d > y > J ? y f ' S ·

È ’y j J E C A .^ i'^ A o . f j y l ' j y ^ y ^ J j A I fJ a L * à ^ a y j t ^

(A 'cj·^ i( o ^ У уа У А 4>>If 0)уО~> u.mU > y J I /Ag ) » y іЛ

ÿ jS y D J A J * -<2«· (J L ^ jy^ ¡ y J \ A j ^ ^-У·^ '•^■^ ^ (_ ¿ ^ J У І.> J ( m La ^ D y* j ¿ I

■ ^ A 'U L g ^ J A iA y

^^_p> j L. y> ' o y jA d o A M c ù / j u y j / , í2¿/¿b^,*¿f i y j J Ѵ У

¿J L fy ÿ ^ A a d y y ^ ^ O ILj, ' У д ^ o ^ a ^ J o y l f ^

^IЫ ^У 'лР ’ ^ с / У А ^ у о у / У І ' о^уУ улЛ ô yb '^U ' î j L Î^ '^ L d i j ^ i j ^ y ^ y ^ , J 0 y y ÿ j 4i) > y y * ^ y j'/J :^ J ' o-^ryAd' fyu» uAjlyux^ o^yt, i/a y j !j

лУ-> oyi J>U>joyoyi l j y , ' ^ y 'y L > 4 fC y j^ J ^ y j ' üLJL a

y .^ J j j J . 'y i “ , bV .^ylj> 0 ^ ^ y y .g ' D j J lAІУ Î ^ y 'y l ^ j ' ^ A Al ' Dy l /M (Aj b fu ^y h J ^ y / d y iL fj^ oyiÏAo U jj ¡¿,J ,

і /У у і- ^ У А у ^ ^ Е у I '^ гУ ^ ‘> A yj' Ы>'іі·' D^cfL>y L*'yy'<y^y •—V Îmc

) J, OA' AJ f' OJj^J;b> Aj ^Aj^JIO J'

Page 132: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

CeVDET

' s * *

Jc£

* u 'cV*- táí e j '^ ' аЬ' аѴ;Х>у L¿->‘ o ^ K f ^ .' л Л л ^ « > 1 y ^ \ '¿ 'j\/y ^- ú > ^ ‘>U-.t <>^X)U»A^y j,ii> j 'ij> о ^ іХ ъ vjs'J» ' JbM ' ti'J aZ >j ¿>'ji ' 1

j . u ,y ,y j u i V y a>j ду і>> v » ir'> ·^ ^ > λ ' Ô/I-*' iS jy J

ÿ i ■>> o / U ' · ; w ^ ¿ ¿ 1>>1Д5 \ІІ1) (2ΐλ>>> ус-»>> \ О l«2A>^(3^ A ^ /J Q:¿ )>'C‘'

İ ^ У ^ S r > i^ } 4^'-? -rV v*-»’- » ^ > b j > » ’ 'W [ J о ¿) <>^ 1^L». '>* ^ GUi’U'yj V \ ^ U y \ Ü’ui»;^^]/^ Ο ψ c ^ j ^ } iS> o ,

< i '-A ^ o ^ \ t- > * с >1з

и?-> ü'>Jü^^ j . u o ^ } ;. ' ^ ^ '¿> u '¿ :.: b V Ц A> .' ^ ’ '-^r Д , u i

: O j> ^ ^ U o y j ' > i > W / x ó i Í ¿ V * ^ J ' > l g > l ¿ О ^ Ц Д с У Ѵ o ' ^ Я * Д 1» , ^ ^ J ^ | J ^ ,Гл I '■

U»_lí· 1»> )b> W \}yC i:)j9 yc4^_ j y ú ^ / y o>Ji J ’ U (b>j^ o > ці O ji i ; ь У

‘l^U ^ly '^İJ Ojji\ W«- . ’> ' ^ ді-.' 3J Uy‘ ¿ ¿ V ^ (^ ¡ jy J ' Ц* ' > J j I ώΛ^j ; u i ^ /‘^> y^ca? A> y*-' o Д у д У - ' L» <»i4* oj/jj-» J / la > \У o j ; j j Чіьі w_;'i¿_;

—^у^сіУД-’иаіі·^·o дд?> ó ^ >>j' ^ ( j u ^ J - j ' j»yi'V,\V,'‘ - ^ ’ j \^j^ Z ^\u \j M ^Á\»^u ■ <y^í> ' JѴ Чл

U.1 ^ 1 tí/-^ 0 >NJ '* y -^ // pa ‘'0<>Д0 V» У ' ¿ y U> cí^j' Д>1 ' Д1^ ' oy J J>oÿ)>f> cùj} I o

' «J>">V*.* o UVi‘ дМ»'_И* β 0'>^ AX) wJï-Ou!4 * «-Jï- O /fj IVUÛ>U-1 r* ' '-^yj ^ УУу “= <iJh_'(JaXis> Уіу } Uö/*>i I/uj^f

' U U L ·

Page 133: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

V - 1 Д -ч 5 - 7· . · ν ? i - î · ? ' ί 5 ^J '}ν . ; ^ Ν ^ d ‘ э . J ^ 4 ; > i \

-;^ \ 4 · ^ · Λ t \

¡ ? . ■ - · » · ^·I - i - v | · \ J i ’ l l ' ’5 і : ·

? ^ ? . ? , Ν · 3 - 7 - і:4 у г f -у ^^ ■% \ · ·5 -:¿ _ ѵ ^ і · о f .< .'-

- 5 · 4 . · - ^ · ί - i l i '

■ Ц у ^ \ ‘Ъ І · ^ ч И '^ - И

I

? Ί · - ^ і \ у х у i 4 ‘ í Í і і - Î

У \ } - {^ · Н ' 1 'о і ? -I 1 ·: I 3 .-..і І, \ :> -; 5 Ε Л · ? « ; . і

' · ' ^ ' ' ^ ^ · í l ■ ^ й ' 5 ■ г і - гя Í Í і-і ] |·» ч ■>■ Í· I і ; 'і5 - І J ' л · V X І , ξ - а ' ' ^ :я - і > \ 4 · ^ - ‘Л г . , î _Ѵ.,5

-■' я ^ ' l í ч ^ '"'■■^ » '·3 І ‘ ^ ' л Ѵ ѵ <У ' І Х . З - і J · ' я 7 .ІІ ' 5 ^ ^ ^ о і '

;?. \ :^ у

Page 134: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

ë ·

/

г».·»,. . i - n ' -" P ■ -

^ f r ^ : ü

f f . І щ

V '^ * ^ - £ 1' - T > / J r ■.,4 t;-· '»' . >=tí. v·· <5ΰ ΛΪ ^ , ®‘ C c r ^ ^

Page 135: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani
Page 136: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

-?ЙЙ., ' : ' ‘ ~ y < ^ ‘f ^ ‘ -.~^'r-^'‘ y i ^ - y ’ , - г , Λ j^./:^;',K r'’'

/С , '*; V f¿;‘ <7//'¿-> V'A '

^ y>.·' '. ·t- ' . · ' . ' , ^ / ^ ^ У У ' - ----- L

''A /iP y ^Уа * J '

y ' * V ·' C» y ^(J i>'Jyi . , ,‘i ' ^ ' · ^ '7 '- ¿y n^/cA y '7'

X A A ^^!A Â C ^'!A ^^У o r^yy O^AJA^yd^^, ^j / / / ] / ^ ' ^ ‘ '' O d Ji(^{yy jd y ji^yjyy j^y ,^ 1;

•'^Ху А / ^ ^ ’‘À'’'-^'^dl/^^^ί^ ’ ->'^d¿> *< /^

r ^

г d d A fA -y y /z id /^ y ^ -^ o y r 'y ^ i',l y ' n d' / Jj SA¿>iyy, ,~-j '

.Ϋ.Ά'/Jj'yy ι/yy'JujyicA A jydly j A. Ч’ ^УуУуА-.У-А уУ> 9 tyy'-J^úyid /// ууУ/ j y ·/ Y4'ó )'/ V УУ-У. 'Ау d y ' ѵу^У'У Á>ji

'^4 К 'с/ ‘'^r> r·^ 1>Г'Г"Ѵ; .'·.jj t^jy 'A44¿‘i ’cdA>y'./¡ >уУУ'уі;й>-'і^^У)4уу

•' Χλ‘44 [:’yi¿s уіу ! ; y . ' r } y . /··' \ *j,4:tyc::X f* 1 ' y ^ '

'X A ^ '' ' ' ' '0 '^ ''^ А ч 4 .Ч ^■f/>y/^^^iíÀ'^Aly' ■ •¥¡>^'''‘ '^ / ' - - '>^ο ··.> '-^d ¡^ : -Y d r v A A y A r fj^ ‘j^ .'.: ,¿ ^ ,,A :y ·; Χ ΐ

^ ///✓V'/j/./j.

AAXA^A 'Y-A·' - <уХ-гУ' 'АчУгУ-сУ.^У í > j ^ X A * ÀÀ

V ^¿^''‘<‘> iÿy/yÿ^ ./-.-y,' i \г ->Уу у л -;у ,ί і і ''y 'd A '> /-’y M y ^ 'y ''’f f - '< ^ 'y '^ ÿ ■ У íΆ У л ■ ,y y ,^ ^ ·¿ ,^ 'J y ,,,y '■ )■ У ¿ '> У \ У А у у < У у .- у ,с у у У : : ,- '^ У М 'у > ^ ' у у у у и У о „ ,у , у ,

^ ''-^ '■τ'Ά '4 / ! Odj'y '-’{А у . (.уу^•у > , ¡у г f d rjyd,^\ P кГ•'у^-А У ·'^ / ( У 'с ё^;у

у ' , I . Ά ''^ ^ '(Χ Χ '4 '·Ά ·<l A ' d 4 ’' ’d^4A''í''^Á0AÍ/i'_j4^Ay'^yX'-‘ii -

J i^y^y¿y-y/ ) ¿y f 'uy ly^'ÿ- 'if/у' I ' Ά df / OjAZ^} уУУА'’. >уУАА' Q yJ/vid0 ö /A 'yA ^ уАг.А/іг:Ау'у:іи t>'^y ,у//[гК>^г— ί· іУу/ V,ν,< tA P /.^ y d '^ iy 'd ' I А у/^ /і- i_ , *\

■J f

V.

1

Page 137: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

ñ ' 7^ ¿ í S : í g : r » : : 2 5 ^ ^

^AsXs"f. ■ ',/T^''/'~f • ■ ' '<'— {S'-, t'·'·'·

' ^■''Уу 0'β’ 'Δ:~^.ύ.

У '- n jy

'' О"·''"'- ·'' '—'~ · -у^ і"~ . Ί Т ·

·^ Ο ,,ι,,// ' s - ■. ■ ^,Ci>-,_^',Í_V-¿v

/— y 'er ^

'у->.K>V

'^^^iyyliУ^í/^y|y/f^j^^^'ÿ^^>Jrf'·/?'Jr'λ¿^'^^'' ‘'■^' /У'Уу^гУууУ'< / / /y '^ry>>/^^y;yiy^y/ui4^Jyyjjyy>jy,yjôi-^yy'-^'^ ; '^■^Я‘f ^^ууу^ууу;У/уА<У.·^У'

^ f ■ ^^Я ''''''^ 'Я '^Я уЯ гЯУууу<:> 'Яу ''' ' ^Яy:■Jy^y-y|¡'yУ^Я .y Я '/ у ѵ, ' · . У , f ' ^ ' í V y ' j ,;^х-і . '. I ' ·· ' ^ ' ' і ' , · . у у .

шЯ " . — ------ 'Z’ '^^^y'yi'y--^yy<^yct^x^>iy^% ^y'y£^yyy*·· ¿¡“ ^ Я 'у 'уу:ууу ‘>ху'у>Уу¡"Яу'· '· ''ÿy '-^ Z y'Ί У .. ■ - ’} ^ уЯ У ^ А у^ уу:Р / _ ^ *> '

, , . ; . У Я у ^ '^ '^ х-'у'ЯуіУ' ^у;; іУУ^У-:‘У у 'Я у^ _ ,/í''^^iW'i/ ί Γ / ' ^ ^ -ѵ ''‘ '''У^У:.Уı с Я ^ ,і і/ У уУ , ! i/yyy('>^Jyy'y d ^ y ^

’ ^ y y y ^ Ç ( f y , y y y y ^ / ^ y ' ' y y d ) * y . ' ^ y . y

A > y Z y > : ^ ¿ '^ л ф у а Я г і^ у ^ 'У ’ іЯ ^ А ^ /У 'У ’ и У у Я я У Я 'у ‘

ó d y i ^ Z A A ' ^ A ' ^ " ' ' ' '·'^·-'·^^''^'^'''' 'Z -^^y (^yy id x^ /id > y‘} ^ Y : 'd y ^ ( ^ - ^ fy^ ' ........................ . y...,ıL·^.dıı;y■^■,/Z^^yyy’ ^ y

' · -J _y ' ·. r :· , Г' '

, 'А І ^ '- А '- 'А 'Я А > У У у['уУ

Page 138: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

i

І - Ѵ Ч

v y j i / J / j Jf ! i ^ ^ xJ·/) ,_,Jjj ¿^)

• ¿Ui í' / ¿XJ/ i/^jjjj^:> Z c^.'y

o Z ^ Ο ϋ μ Z y z ) ^ J J ¿ / í y j ^ y J ' ) , i j y i ¿ t j j i_,

(/'- ' í ^ j l Ι'ύi ^ l i í ^ ) j ¿ < ' / ) j ^ J ¿* *> ^ j y < y j ^ ) i } j J } / Z ^ M

'уУ 19 "Г о

----------------------

4 )

/ / ' L > / /УУ J ^ ) ) ^ Г ß I f J )уУ Í ! У /

______f X J ^ f j Í / - 4 )

. 'Ьл9у/^с /0 ¡ í j - j ^ u J h J ^^ j> J j j u i f ( / j Z )

■'■''ÂJfiJ

yjjyo '’ ^y

У-У І-Уу/^ }^·^·^J У / Л

\ ' \ <

y -A

A.:

.\ TA·:.·-%n

/ / .

^ ■’■ ' 9 O U l v i j i j y i / f ^ У /.'С у '

Q lU L·^ w r . ’ y / y * ' · / ' / ' ‘/ I '

r(/jy/9/ y y ^ \ y V 'у у /

¿ J j - h u y . v > · ,^ v , ^ ) і У ^ ,‘ j 7 / · · ' y

Page 139: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

/ й р f o

PInS'.'

}1

JT..

η

к:

I|iIl;

íi

" Έi

Ѵ У '- ' V ^ s y ' o j ' ^

( i ù ÿ y y j ^ ‘ 'J /'S ^ J Ú à

7>i ^

iI *>í . \^ \ i

í<. cX /

\c/L<·

C ' ¿ ' o ^ d y t ^ ^

J ^ Ü > ¿ / p ) ^ ύ < /л ^> <>^У/ s ^ '^ J ^ j) ,

¿ : , Л ’^ 'Л Ф / у ^ ' ' · ' ^' * / ^ ^ -Г

y j y р· ■' 'Т'ЛфУзф'сУо </íW ·

i ' - V - ^ ' ' k f f ^ J ¿ M ^ < ^ и У < { 5 /

c<

c/'

y · í > y ¿ ^ i ^ ^ f y 'J 'y ^ j j y / ^

l ·

y ' L ^ j j ) c j y j)< r^ ip i j '/л У У у У л / У У

i/y /í O J^ y У іуі ^

^ O v ^ ^,( '"- ‘·) r -^^4

У у у ' р ( ^ i ^ ( f j ( y y v j j ? / j

ú -V W

ii

^ ^ y j ' j ' j J e ^ y j ; f O ^

УУ'У ' ' '' ■>'4! ¿"'(Л." ’.J> y t / i ) j j ü ; ' ^ y ) S / j M j i P j j

^ . . y * .( / / Í/yútv¿X'y-yv · ^

Page 140: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

C \ } \ /M

i l · Ч ist

ΐ

!г-il

ЛАР 4-i

c j j j j ; / t P í Ve», ;y e v / i c^^ ./cr i^ /

• ^ ^ % · ' · * yy** * [ y /

' ' ^ ' x · I

(

Λ , V ------ - ''^ ^ ^ ^^ -^c /J J ¡ /J \Ú f} / Á J · ^ Á u b '

^ 'Y i ^ J xY ·

P^/uf

IV (f^yJ /y jfy { i^ y )(^ ß { J /^ /^ J f^ l t / ' c ^ / ß / j ß y ' }γ ; зU^AJ)

Page 141: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

4 > !^ ’! ^ ’’ΐΐ'^ ·'·> > ^ ^ ^ ί^ ^

/ с ъ J

с > "^У // ^ O jy \^ r · ' ^ l ^ * ¿ J j J y > ^ f ^ J l L i S ^ 0 - j }¿ fju)

у у ІУ ^ У\ / ^ 1 \j\f J W гу ' у ^ * у \У^

■ ^ y v /,í/,J ¿ b )^ ¿ < i) tíf /> ¡ ^ y ? f l/^ .íí^ ^

''С е

''Ç»

4 ^ > ' к ÿ ’l 4 / ^ i ü i y , ; à j y , ^ / , ) 4 j '

* - .

/И о «у

. і

л.· ·.·■·;. ^^л і'ѵ··'-'»'« s

Page 142: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

VN

ff• г*Ѵч.

‘ > /

' • ¿ ϊ .1 « ü d Opn^

y ' j J j i i ^ ¡ ^ , j j j , ^ , j ¿ í. ; /

ЙЛ ' . ' . у / /■ .

ЛАГ) 'á.%^ к ^

| 3 ^Ч ‘\ V-'

I'

V

4 / { ¡ ) · У · - / - ' . /

r ■ < .. . , ../-.к |,.> .,S;^^·. ,.-:^,.іі.

Page 143: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

· · “ ■ ^ • ' ^ Ѵ :

“ ‘'-5; Ф'ІS . І 4 1 ,

-'$■ ' 5 · ' ί · ? ч ^

• 4 ' ^ ‘\ ί > | · ?

-л а Í ^ : S ?

^ Ѵ -/

Page 144: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

V \ ^ ·.

rμ Ρ Ί

ID\

Ч - V

'V *

' .- - / . · . : ) у / .

v^fyó I

î^jj> / > " * / ¿ U j

r ' ^ / j y k J " ^ ''( / 'J / ^ y j

J ¿ y } j y ' Ѵ ' ' у С р ) { ’ - '.' у/

* ^ /£ ï

■ · / - ^

Page 145: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

/ /

i t / - ΐ. -.¡1 -V· / gr

> ;//

V »

« J

I

I

......I

Page 146: ‘ .-w* ЧІІ І ( . j -,-'ί í li ¡ 1 Гй, TT o i/ІА i i Hi/i. 'i 7-50 Studies on the Economic History of the Middle East TED Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi TOEM Tarih-i Osmani

m h í r r ,

. . . ,

[ f j y ^ j ‘¿^j}Jcyj/)jJ>,4:^f^jJJ^JjJ^jJj^^í i^y^/yf t^y i))Ó ^Jj;} ^ '/'f.y

'уУ/ o f y j

/J'n _ - . ' · - · /é,\y:^Cyi'friAj^ <ійі>^> }¿j j УуУ ь ^'л^> jf} ■'/^ lí é)f‘. JS cX^oJj¡ ■ 1/

- ' · / * ■ ¿У У уГy / j y j ^ > J k l y-V

-

i ё 'У ‘уУ уі/ ( j / j ^ y

^ > ¥ - ^ y ß y .y p ! /: t> ,

✓ !г ySyjjJ

• l , c ,

'У гЬ ^х—Ц ) y

~^¿

/y уКс У '/ f ' / ? y y ‘ і у У о У У

■ І У У ' ^ У^ 0^5/У > и ?Д у ; J , ' У ір -'У У У /)

i ' 2 p ) / У / f j o 'yjCjsC i

f,L/

f ‘ Л^) i / J...y '-J :^У'> f í j/*j(é/ г- '/р

' t w <

* ^ с і и^ '<" Ы

/ y -I- - ' i y - í i• ' ^ ^ ' ^ - ' ^ y ^ , ' v ;

- Й*· * '^ Ѣ ê ^ ^ é

ú · ·' CVy · . ·]

4 - r - ^ . P ^ ’/ . r í P \ , / . . , Á J y > i / y y / . · . . .' : . . ./ Л \ о / / CI)'jμ!gЧ/ ' ' ^ P f y V v ' < ^ J X À > n / ^ ^ i J f ¿ -y ' - ‘ f f ? ¿ } > ' / y : y j i j y i > ] j o í v / ! ¿ v i /

y / y ^ j í ' l · y j ¿ ¿ у/У У :, у л о , ; y ·>

2^«^" ''· ' rj!j‘(^'^Jj f f ѵУу y ) j \ , J j j j / o

•M